Documents menu
Organized labour and economic liberalization. India: Past, present and
future
By Debashish Bhattacherjee, Indian Institute of Management, Calcutta,
n.d. (year 2000)
Executive Summary
1.Introduction
2.Contrasting views on trade unions as
institutions. A comparative framework
3.The changing economic environment and its effects
on organized labour in India
3.1The four phases of unionism: An evolutionary approach
3.1.1 The first phase of unionism (1950 to mid-1960s)
Commentary
3.1.2 The second phase of unionism (mid-1960s to 1979)
Commentary
3.1.3 The third phase of unionism (1980-1991)
Commentary
3.1.4 The fourth phase of unionism (1992-2000)
Commentary
3.2 The issues
3.2.1 Unionization and employment
3.2.2 Union structure and union density
3.2.3 Wages and working conditions
3.2.4 Collective bargaining
3.2.5 Industrial conflict
3.2.6 Labour management relations
3.2.7 Inter-state variations
3.2.8 Women workers and unionization
3.2.9 Changing public perception of trade unions
4.Future role of trade unions in India: Organizing the unorganized
4.1 The private corporate sector
4.2 Public sector enterprises
4.3The informal sector
References
Appendix: Tables
Table 1. Employment in the organized sector (in 000,000s)
Table 2. Number of registered unions and membership of unions submitting returns
Table 3. Industrial conflict (1950-1997)
Table 4. Economic indicators
Table 5. Employment elasticities in major sectors
Table 6. Sectoral distribution of employment in the formal economy (in 000,000s)
Table 7. Sector-wise number and membership of trade unions submitting returns
Table 8. Index numbers of consumer prices (1960-61 to 1993-94)
Table 9. Index number of wage rates
Table 10. Real wages in organized manufacturing, 1960/61 - 1983/84
Table 11. State-wise number and membership of trade unions submitting returns
Executive Summary
This paper examines the role of organized labour in India in a
structural and historical context. It attempts to trace the economic,
political and social effects of the trade union movement and its
strategies over time. These effects are felt at enterprise- and/or
firm-level, industry-level, regional and national level. First we
consider the effect of changing economic conditions on the evolution
of trade unions and bargaining institutions in largely urban labour
markets in the post-independence period (1947 onwards). Some
contemporary issues affecting the organized labour movement in India
today are then discussed.
This essay has two main objectives: (a) to present a history of Indian
industrial relations, broadly understood as the changing relationships
between workers, trade unions, employers, the economy and the state;
(b) to posit a political economy of trade unionism in India.
The evolution of trade unionism (and industrial relations in general)
is described in terms of the "four phases of unionism". This
corresponds with structural changes in the economy and we trace the
effect of these changes on labour markets as well as on the (very
broadly defined) industrial relations arena. The first phase (1950 to
mid-1960s) corresponds to an era of state planning and import
substitution, when public-sector employment and public-sector unionism
rose phenomenally. Unions and bargaining structures were highly
centralized; the two main federations were the nationalist Indian
National Trade Union Congress and the communist All India Trade Union
Congress. State intervention in the determination of wages and
working conditions was the norm and "state-dominated
pluralism" was the labour regime during this first phase.
The second phase (mid-1960s to 1979) is associated with a period of
economic stagnation and political turmoil. Employment slowed down,
there were massive inter-union rivalries, and industrial conflict
increased. Centralized bargaining institutions now started feeling
the pressure of dissent from below, and both the Hind Mazdoor Sabha
and the Centre of Indian Trade Unions made significant progress in the
labour movement. The crisis culminated in the May 1974 railway strike
that was followed by the 1975-77 Emergency Regime of Mrs. Gandhi. An
"involuted" pluralism dominated Indian labour relations during
this second phase.
The third phase (1980-1991) corresponds to a period of segmented and
uneven economic development. Decentralized bargaining and independent
trade unionism enter the stage in a significant way. Two major
strikes (the 1980/81 Bangalore public-sector strike and the 1982
Mumbai textile workers strike) marked this phase, and inter-state and
inter-regional variations in the nature of labour-management regimes
became much wider. In the more profitable economic sectors the unions
gained, but in the unorganized and declining sector, workers lost out
and unions were left with few strategies.
Finally, the fourth phase of unionism (as yet incomplete, 1991-2000)
represents the post-economic reform period. The stabilization and
structural adjustment programmes led to demands for increased labour
market flexibility, especially employment flexibility. This has led
to a recruitment freeze in many public sector sites, and unions in
these sectors now have to cope with competition at local level. In
non-viable public enterprises, unions are coming to terms with
"voluntary" retirement schemes. In the early years of
economic reform there were sincere attempts by all parties to engage
in tripartite consultations, but there now seem to be several barriers
to this form of engagement.
The essay then gives a more detailed presentation of crucial issues
which are particularly relevant to the trade union movement in India
today. These are: the relationship between unionization and
employment; union structure and union density; wages and working
conditions; the changing nature of collective bargaining; changing
patterns of industrial conflict; the nature of labour-management
relations; the (extremely important) issue of inter-state and regional
variations in labour regimes; the question of women workers and
unionization; and the changing public perception of trade unions. The
main findings are summarized below.
- In both the public and private sectors, employment in industry
has substantially declined, especially since the economic reforms;
however, employment in public sector services has increased since the
third phase of unionism. The trend in most industries is to reduce
permanent employment and to use more contract, temporary and casual
workers.
- Trade unions have performed well in profitable industries,
mainly in private (often multinational) enterprises, but also in some
public sector firms with decentralized bargaining structures. However,
they lack new strategies in the older and declining sectors of
production where industry-wide bargaining structures are typically the
norm. Whereas workers and unions in non-viable public enterprises are
facing closure and an uncertain future, centralized unions
representing employees in public services remain strong due to the
monopolistic nature of their product markets.
- The number of plant-based independent and unaffiliated trade
unions has risen, which may have caused a decline in the power of
centralized affiliated unions, especially in the private sector.
- Two critical changes in collective bargaining are the expansion
of coverage and scope of long-term agreements. Competitive market
pressures, especially since the beginning of economic reform, have
forced bargaining outcomes to be decided at local level.
- The procedural environment required for competitive industrial
pluralism to work at its best is still absent from the Indian
industrial relations system (absence of a secret ballot, absence of a
single bargaining agent, absence of third-party arbitration and strong
restraints on "legal" strikes). This makes the organized
labour movement still very dependent on state recognition and
patronage. All parties recognize the urgent need for comprehensive
labour law reform.
- Modern human resources management has significantly altered
labour-management relations in the advanced sectors of production
without necessarily leading to a decline in union bargaining
power.
- Inter-state and inter-city variations in labour-management
relations have increased since the mid-1980s, and in the absence of a
concerted effort on the part of the central government to reform
labour laws, these variations are likely to be accentuated with the
progress of economic reform.
- Women workers are largely concentrated in the self-employed and
unorganized sectors with little representation in trade
unions. Non-governmental organizations have made considerable efforts
to organize women in these vulnerable occupations.
The paper concludes with a discussion of the future role of
trade unions, concentrating on the unionization of informal sector
workers. Given the low levels of unionization in India (relative to
comparable countries), and given that a large proportion of workers
are employed in the informal sector (a trend which is likely to
intensify with the economic reforms currently underway), the trade
union movement has to make a determined effort to organize informal
sector workers. This calls for concerted action on the part of the
centralized trade union federations in alliance with other social
movements and non-governmental organizations. It is only through this
kind of extensive mobilization that "public action" can be
triggered to "level-up" the labour market institutions of
vulnerable sections of the workforce.
The organized labour movement will have to come to terms with global
competition, technology, new industrial organization and
structural/demographic changes in the workforce. The earlier,
relatively insulated, systems for regulating employment will have to
give way to more market-sensitive and flexible systems, ultimately
even in the public sphere. Unions, especially in the service sector,
will have to become sensitive to consumer needs. In the private
sector, trade unions have adapted their structures in response to the
decentralization of industrial relations, but these adjustments are
painful and difficult in the public sector. There is no other way but
to increase membership, which means organizing vulnerable workers in
the informal sector. This is the most obvious way for unions to win
broader community support. Finally, trade unions can only gain by
cooperating and working together. Perhaps the new millennium will
witness a series of mergers leading to a united and independent labour
movement.
1. Introduction
This paper examines the role of organized labour in India in a
structural and historical context, tracing the economic, political,
and social effects of the trade union movement over time. We look at
union strategies at the level of the enterprise and/or firm, the
industry, the region and the nation. The effect of changing economic
conditions on the evolution of trade unions and bargaining
institutions are described in largely urban labour markets in the
post-independence period (1947 onwards). Then we consider some
contemporary issues affecting the organized labour movement in India
today.
The paper has two main objectives: a) to present a history of Indian
industrial relations, broadly understood as the changing relationships
between workers, trade unions, employers, the economy and the state;
and b) to posit a political economy of trade unionism in India. The
contrasting views of Freeman and Medoff (1984) of trade unions as
"monopoly" institutions, or as the "collective voice"
of workers serves as a theoretical framework here. From a policy
perspective in democratic and pluralistic societies, the objective
must be to minimize the "monopoly" effects and to strengthen
the "collective voice" effects.
The position taken here is "that the evolution of labour
institutions is determined by the objective interests of social groups
inherent in the logic of a modern industrial society" (Zeitlin,
1987, p. 163), and that these "interests" are inevitably
"ambiguous and context dependent". Consequently, it is
difficult to establish mechanisms to ensure that labour institutions,
such as trade unions, collective bargaining and the state, continue to
play the parts assigned to them. The second proposition of this essay
is that "no single approach to the study of labour organization is
at present adequate - which is to say that the study of these matters
is usually informed from several points of view" (Williamson,
1985, p. 241).
The organization of the paper is as follows. Section 2 provides a
comparative framework by examining some proposals regarding union
behaviour, economic performance and industrial/labour relations
strategy. Section 3, on the changing economic environment and its
effects on organized labour in India, consists of two parts. The
first part expounds the "four phases of unionism". The second
part deals with unionization and employment, union structure and
density, wages and working conditions, collective bargaining,
industrial conflict, labour-management relations, inter-state
variations, women workers and unionization, and the changing public
perception of trade unions. The concluding section comments on the
future role of trade unions in India, with a focus on organizing
non-unionized workers.
2. Contrasting views on trade unions as institutions
Freeman and Medoff (1984) examined the impact of unionism on the
employment relationship in the US economy, contrasting the "two
faces of unionism": the "monopoly" versus the
"collective voice" view. These lead to a completely divergent
analysis of the union as an economic and political institution; the
policy implications of the two views are therefore fundamentally
incompatible.
The first view analyses unions as large monopolies in the labour
market whose basic objective is to increase their members' wages above
the market level by restricting labour supply. This "wage
mark-up" leads to a misallocation of human and capital resources,
and is therefore not only economically suboptimal, but may also be
socially undesirable in that it leads to greater inequalities within
the workforce. In addition, strikes of all kinds impose an easily
measurable loss on the economy. Finally, "union work rules",
embedded in contract provisions often lower the productivity of both
labour and capital by creating inflexibilities at the workplace.
While these arguments typically emanate from free-market economists,
social theorists who subscribe to this view often characterize unions
as undemocratic and crime-riddled institutions.
In sharp contrast, the collective voice view asserts that unions have
positive economic, political and social effects in pluralist
democracies. The union's collective voice, determined by a
"median voter", provides management with information on
workplace and shopfloor issues, acting as a communication channel.
This leads to the development and retention of specific skills,
improves worker morale, provides conditions that eliminate quitting,
and enables the union to pressure management to act fairly and
efficiently in its daily operations. It is believed that unionized
work environments are more productive than comparable non-unionized
environments. Finally, unions are socially beneficial as they
represent the interests of lower income groups and vulnerable sections
of society.
Using the above framework, Freeman and Medoff examine union effects on
economic efficiency and the distribution of income. They also examine
the social nature of the union as an institution of modern industrial
society. Questions about economic efficiency usually relate to
whether unions enhance productivity through their collective voice or
whether they block technological change through "monopoly"
routes, such as inflexible contract provisions. These often compel
employers to substitute capital for labour and to invest in better
"quality" labour. This leads to productivity growth only in
the sectors concerned, at the cost of overall employment growth in the
economy. Questions relating to income distribution have to do with
the effects of unions on non-unionized and unorganized workers. That
is, do unions have positive or negative "spillover" effects on
unorganized labour markets? Generally speaking, the higher the degree
of unionization in an economy, the greater are the positive spillover
effects and the smaller the wage inequalities within the workforce.
Finally, the "monopoly" view holds that unions fight for their
own selfish interests at the expense of others, and blames their
political lobbying for bureaucratic and corrupt practices. The
"collective voice" view sees unions as the economic and
political institutions of the weaker segments of society.
It is clear that the political charter of the "collective
voice" is based on pluralistic democratic principles, enlightened
management and responsible trade unionism (Turnbull, 1991). The
crucial assumptions of the "collective voice" are the
following: (a) political and industrial pluralism; (b) interest group
politics being played out in a multi-party regime of political
liberalism; (c) a strong belief in the efficiency and fairness of
"regulated conflict"; (d) an efficient and fair procedural
environment, which implies the just implementation of unambiguous
labour laws and a degree of symmetry among adversaries' bargaining
resources; and, finally (e) trust in neutral third-party arbitration
when confronted with a labour relations impasse. According to
Williamson (1985, p. 241), "the institution of arbitration lies
at the core of industrial pluralism". The basic premise of
pluralist bargaining is that interest group conflict approximates the
public interest. This paper explores the extent to which the
assumptions and beliefs of pluralist industrial relations have evolved
in India as structural changes have taken place and the political
economy has developed.
A comparative framework
It is now a truism that economic performance is related to the nature
of labour market institutions (see Horton et al., 1991; Nelson, 1991;
Freeman, 1992; Buchele and Christiansen, 1992). Economic performance
here means controlling inflation and generating employment, which
implies productivity growth. In the world of unions and collective
negotiations, the key variables frequently cited as determining
economic performance are: the level at which bargaining takes place
(plant, firm, industry/region, nation), and the nature of trade union
structures.
Until at least the mid-1980s, the literature suggested that economies
with a decentralized bargaining structure (enterprise-based unions
negotiating at plant and firm level, as in East Asian countries, Japan
and Switzerland) and economies with a centralized bargaining structure
(national agreements with centralized trade union federations, as in
Austria, Norway and Sweden) "performed" better than economies
having industry-wide agreements with industry-wide unions, as in the
US and UK. Put another way, "collective voice" effects seem
to be maximized in centralized bargaining structures, whereas
"monopoly" effects seem to be greatest at medium levels of
centralization. This is the famous "Calmfors-Driffil"
relationship, based on the premise that the extent of
labour-management cooperation (or conflict) is determined by the
degree of centralization of the bargaining institutions. Its relevance
to developing countries was examined by Nelson (1991), the argument
being that as centralized labour market institutions cannot easily be
replicated in these countries, decentralized labour institutions may
be the most efficient arrangement (see Horton et al., 1991). The whole
debate on labour market flexibility and globalization is concerned
with the degree of decentralization of labour market institutions (see
for example, Katz, 1993).
While most commentators would agree that labour market flexibility is
required for facilitating economic restructuring, heated controversy
surrounds the question of how this flexibility is to be achieved. As
transition will involve considerable social costs, what is to be the
role of the state and the trade union movement in managing this
transition? The debate acquired particular significance with the
release of the World Bank World Development Report:
Workers in an integrating world (1995) and an ILO
report: World Employment 1996-97 - National policies in a
global context.
(Endnote 1)
The World Bank Report
hypothesizes increasing employment and labour incomes with greater
integration of nations into the global market, positing a reduced role
of the state in the labour market and expecting trade unions to be
responsible and non-political. On the other hand, the central message
of the ILO Report is that state intervention with centralized
bargaining institutions can return economies to full employment
policies, which it sees as the only way to create jobs and better
earnings opportunities (D'Souza, 1998).
Where does India fit in this comparative framework? The Indian
economy represents a mix of all three bargaining levels and a variety
of union structures. In the private corporate sector, plant-level
bargaining takes place with enterprise-based unions that may or may
not be affiliated to parliamentary political parties. In
public-sector enterprises, centralized trade union federations
affiliated to political parties bargain with the state (as employer)
at industry-and/or national-level. Central and state government
employees in the service sector (transport, postal services, banking
and insurance, police and firefighters, etc.) are usually represented
by politically affiliated unions bargaining at national and/or
regional level. Most of these centralized bargaining and union
structures were stable during the period of planned industrialization
while India pursued a policy of import substitution. However, since
the mid-1980s the economy has opened up to greater domestic and
international competition, and these structures have come under
increasing pressure to decentralize. These pressures have become
stronger since the economic liberalization programme was introduced in
1991, especially in the public sector. As in other countries, the
state has gradually retreated from its earlier role of creating
permanent employment and regulating union-management bargaining.
India has had mixed experience with creating labour institutions that
are compatible with a pluralist industrial relations model. In the
early years, the government officially promoted industrial pluralism
and bilateral collective bargaining, but the institutions responsible
for this were largely controlled by the state. This
"state-dominated" pluralism, coupled with ambiguous labour
laws regarding trade union recognition and "industrial
disputes", eventually led to a multiplicity of party-based trade
unions. This considerably weakened the political power of the
organized labour movement as a whole, although in some strategic sites
in the public sector centralized unions had considerable bargaining
strength. Although unions could impose severe costs on key sectors of
the economy, the organized labour movement as a whole was not strong
enough to impose a cooperative solution at national level. This is
still true today.
With economic liberalization, competitive forces began to affect the
structure of the union movement. In several private enterprises,
"independent" rank-and-file led unions came into existence and
engaged in informed and militant bargaining, often with multinational
employers, securing substantial wage and non-wage gains in the
process. As these unions "traded off" increased wages against
employment growth, and as employers shifted to "outsourcing"
from non-union sites, the traditional party-based unions found their
potential recruitment terrain both challenged and curtailed. More
recently, since the liberalization process officially began in 1992,
many of these centralized party-based unions have united under a
common front to resist government attempts at privatization and
decentralization in the public sector. However, the organized labour
movement as a comprehensive organization continues to face a fractured
and segmented constituency, divided by skill, region, industry and
ethnicity. In addition, major labour law reform continues as an
unfinished (and forever postponed) agenda.
In terms of the "monopoly" versus the "collective
voice" framework, the early years after independence witnessed the
state acting as the 'collective voice' of workers for the purpose of
rapid industrialization with minimum industrial strife. In so doing,
the state minimized the potential "monopoly" effects, wages
and working conditions were administered rather than decided through
collective negotiations in the public sector. An implicit
"incomes policy" kept the "'union wage mark-up" in
check. Over time, however, as both inter- and intra- industry
differentiation developed, especially within the private sector,
other, more radical and militant, union "voices" emerged that
quite effectively began to challenge the state hold on the organized
labour movement. In the private sector, efficient productivity
bargaining with informed unions kept "monopoly" effects within
the firm in check while "collective voice" effects increased.
However, in public sector enterprises and services, the union
"voice" led to rigid and inflexible contract provisions. With
pay increases unrelated to improvements in productivity, union
"monopoly" effects intensified. There seems to be some
agreement now among labour commentators and researchers that (since at
least the early 1980s) some segments of the organized workforce made
substantial wage and non-wage gains in the more profitable sectors of
production. The large majority of workers, however, continue to face
increasing employment insecurity, if not lower wage growth, both in
declining industries in the formal sector and in the growing informal
sectors. With the onset of economic liberalization, these
"negative union spillover" effects may accentuate inequalities
within the workforce. Clearly there is need for a concerted attempt by
the state and the organized labour movement to actively reverse these
trends by levelling-up the labour market institutions which affect the
wages and working conditions of the unorganized.
3. The changing economic environment and its effects on
organized labour in India
3.1 The four phases of unionism: An evolutionary approach
3.1.1 The first phase of unionism
(1950 to mid-1960s)
The first phase of the (post-independence)
(Endnote 2) Indian trade
union movement generally corresponds to the first three Five-Year Plans
(1951-56, 1956-61, 1961-66), a period of "national capitalism". A state-led
industrialization policy with an import substitution strategy resulted
in the formation of large, employment-intensive public sector
enterprises, mostly in the capital and intermediate goods sectors.
This massive development of the public sector aided the private
corporate sector in terms of supplying the necessary intermediate and
capital goods (Desai, 1975). Between 1951 and 1965, industrial
production increased at an average annual rate of 7.7 per cent, and
manufacturing output increased at the rate of 7.6 per cent (Nayyar,
1981). High growth rates were sustained by public investment in
capital and intermediate goods, while growth in consumer durables
slowed down. Rigid import-substitution policies guaranteed the
domestic market and stimulated private sector investment (Patnaik and
Rao, 1977).
The expansion of large public enterprises led to employment growth in
the formal economy, mainly in such enterprises, but also in the
private sector, notably in services, transport and education. Average
employment growth increased rapidly from around 0.4 per cent per annum
from 1951 to 1956 to around 2 per cent per annum from 1961 to 1966
(Papola, 1994). Public sector employment quite naturally led to
public sector unionism. The number of registered trade unions
increased from 4,623 in 1951/52 to 11,614 in 1961/62; membership in
the registered unions that submitted returns more than tripled during
this period (Venkataratnam, 1996).
(Endnote 3)
The communist-led All India Trade Union Congress (AITUC) had dominated
the organized labour movement since before independence (for example,
in the textile and engineering industries of Mumbai, Calcutta,
Kanpur). The growing public sector now provided a new terrain for
large- scale unionization. It is here that the Congress
Party-controlled Indian National Trade Union Congress (INTUC) made
early inroads. Unlike the AITUC, which rose from the rank and file,
the INTUC was imposed on the labour movement from the outside. There
were no ambiguities in the chain of command from party to union. As
(the then) Prime Minister Nehru stated (Chatterjee, 1980, p. 152):
It goes without saying that the INTUC has been sponsored and nursed
mostly by Congressmen and derives its strength from the moral and
other support of the Congress…….…it is imperative that in all
political matters all Congressmen working in the INTUC should treat
the Congress as its supreme body and abide by its code of conduct.
Myron Weiner's (1962, p. 78) observation of the INTUC leadership was
succinct: "Their loyalties are to the Congress Party, then to the
present (Congress) government, to the nation and last of all to the
workers who belong to their unions." When confronted with a choice
between the patronage of the ruling party and genuine worker support,
the INTUC usually opted for the former (Chatterjee, 1980). Since
chief ministers, labour commissioners, registrars of trade unions,
inspectors, conciliators, tribunal officials, magistrates, police
officers and all other officials who dealt with unions (during this
first phase) were appointed by the Congress government, management
officials were often requested or pressured to assist INTUC unions to
establish themselves or defeat rival unions (Kennedy, 1966).
This relationship between the state (i.e. ruling government) and its
affiliated trade union federation during the first phase of unionism
seems to have tied in neatly with the provisions of the Industrial
Disputes Act (IDA) of 1947 which, according to Datta Chaudhuri (1996,
p. 12), is "the single most important piece of legislation between
the worker and his employer". The Act makes no provision for
procedures to determine the representative union in what would
normally be a single bargaining unit, and as employers were under no
legal obligation to bargain with unions, there were no built-in
incentives for either party to engage in collective bargaining. Early
writings on Indian industrial relations consistently pointed to this
aspect of the Industrial Disputes Act and the way in which it impeded
collective bargaining during this period (Kennedy, 1966; Punekar,
1966). Coupled with this was the Indian Trade Union Act of 1926; the
Act allowed any seven workers to register their trade union, but made
no provision for union recognition (e.g. through a "secret
ballot" procedure). While the opposition unions were for a
"secret ballot" to determine union strength, the INTUC was
against it, favouring instead the "check-off" system of
membership receipts, a system that could easily be manipulated.
(Endnote 5)
after the Labour Minister who resigned in protest, and many
commentators see this as a major setback to the development of a
mature industrial relations system (Ramaswamy, 1984). In more
contemporary language, it may have been a strategic mistake:
one can only imagine how the industrial relations system would have
developed if the "Giri Approach" had been adopted.
State intervention in the determination of wages and working
conditions was the norm during the first phase; wages were determined
by political and institutional considerations (Myers, 1958; Fonseca,
1964; Jackson, 1972). The structure of bargaining was very
centralized, usually at national level, but at industry level in some
regions (e.g. Mumbai textiles). In a few cases private- sector
bargaining was at enterprise level. Wage determination during this
first phase was known at the time as "tripartism" and
"political bargaining".
In terms of the movement of real wages of industrial workers during
this first phase, India was held out as an example of the Lewis model
of growth at work, with both product and consumption wage growing
slower than labour productivity (Jackson, 1972). Low unionization,
inter-union rivalries sharpened by political affiliation, excess
supply of labour and state intervention of a complex and peculiar type
contributed to a wage lag (Deshpande, 1992). As the famous Report of
the National Commission on Labour (1969), examining the real wages of
industrial workers for the period 1951-64, stated: "increases in
money wages of industrial workers since Independence have not been
associated with a rise in real wages nor have real wage increases been
commensurate with improvements in productivity". The labour
relations regime promoted "responsible unionism" subject to
maintaining industrial peace (Johri, 1967). Both the number of strikes
and the number of workers involved in strikes during the first phase
were significantly lower than during the second phase and beyond
(Johri, 1967; Sengupta, 1992). By the end of the first phase of
unionism, further splits had occurred in the labour movement: the
Socialists broke away from the Congress and formed their own trade
union federation, the Hind Mazdoor Sabha (HMS), and during the
Indo-Chinese conflict, the radicals broke away from the Communist
Party of India and formed the Communist Party of India (Marxist) which
generated its own trade union, the Centre of Indian Trade Unions
(CITU).
Commentary
The first phase of unionism represented a period of state-driven
industrialization that possibly required the government to guide or
control the labour movement. At enterprise level, the capital-labour
relationship was dominated by a paternalistic labour relations system
based on the belief that the state knew more about workers' needs than
they did themselves. In this way, the state appropriated the various
"union voices" for the "collective" purpose of rapid
industrialization with minimum industrial strife. In public sector
enterprises and services, internal labour markets (Endnote 6) generated social harmony and a
feeling of belonging.
Given the large number of statutes governing the terms and general
conditions of employment(Endnote
7)
it is clear that the state attempted to execute the "idea of a
national minimum". However, freedom to contract between capital
and labour was restricted and mediated through the state. In
addition, the idea of planned and rapid industrialization possibly
excluded the basic premise of mature industrial pluralism, i.e. the
belief that "regulated conflict" can be both productive to the
economy and fair to the involved parties.
During this first phase of unionism, few strategic choices were open
to unions or to employers as labour relations outcomes were
over-determined by the state. The institutional structures that
facilitate efficient collective bargaining remained underdeveloped.
Government attempts at developing participatory choices at the small
group level, through its legislated Work Committees (1947) and later
through Joint Management Councils (1958), received at best a lukewarm
response from management and unions (Venkataratnam, 1996).
During this first phase, union "voice" effects were probably
larger than "monopoly" effects, as both unionization and
employment in the organized sector increased significantly (see tables
1 and 2). In addition, given a phenomenal rise in the number of
registered trade unions during this phase, one could argue that there
were positive union spillover effects to previously unorganized
sectors.
3.1.2 The second phase of
unionism (mid-1960s to 1979)
The second phase of unionism more or less corresponds with the Annual
Plans for 1967-69, the Fourth (1969-74) and Fifth (1974-79) Five-Year
Plans. "The rate of inflation rose above the politically sensitive
danger-mark of 10 per cent in 1966/67 and 1967/68, and food price
inflation was even higher (around 20 per cent)" (Joshi and Little,
1994, p. 48). Inflation worsened in 1973/74 and there were food riots
in various states. The period is associated with industrial
stagnation (Nayyar, 1981). Thus, between 1965 and 1975, the average
annual rate of growth in total industrial production and in
manufacturing output increased at only 3.6 per cent and 3.1 per cent
respectively (Nayyar, 1981). Political economists have posited
various explanations for this slowdown: the deceleration in public
investment (Raj, 1976; Vaidyanathan, 1977; Patnaik and Rao, 1977), the
unequal terms of trade between agriculture and industry (Mitra, 1977),
the inefficiencies of state regulation in the public sector (Bhagwati
and Srinivasan, 1975), and changes in the structure of demand
resulting from growing income inequalities (Nayyar, 1981).(Endnote 8)
In addition, the economy suffered oil price shocks in 1973 and in
1978. During this phase, especially during the Fourth and Fifth
Five-Year Plans, actual growth rates for industrial production were
far below plan targets (Ahluwalia, 1991, p. 11). It is quite clear
that the deceleration adversely affected the level of employment in
the economy as a whole.
Structural changes in the economy obviously had an effect on union
activity, collective bargaining practices, industrial labour markets,
and labour relations in general. There was a dramatic increase in the
number of disputes (strikes and lockouts), the number of workers
involved and the number of workdays lost between 1966 and 1974
(Sengupta, 1992). New forms of protest, such as the
"hartal" (go-slow), often resulting in considerable
violence, emerged during this second phase. In certain regions, such
as West Bengal, these were used quite frequently and effectively,
leading to a significant outflow of capital to other parts of the
country.
Disillusionment with the INTUC's internal practices and its
ineffectiveness at enterprise level led to a proliferation of unions
affiliated to other, more radical, political organizations during the
first part of this second phase. Workers sought more skilled
politicians and negotiators to lead their struggles. The relationship
between the rank and file and outside leadership in the non-INTUC
unions could be characterized, to use Holmstrom's (1984, p. 289)
phrase, as "a transaction between the membership and a politician
known as a good negotiator". Two demographic factors may be
associated with this change in worker preferences: a) a growing
proportion of workers were young people who had not participated in
the pre-independence labour struggles; and b) (probably more
important), the leaders of the radical unions at this time were mostly
not party politicians but committed lawyers and student activists
well-versed in the bureaucratic rites of the Indian industrial
relations system (Chatterjee, 1980). An analysis of industrial
disputes by "union-type" revealed that the number of disputes
involving two or more central trade union federations increased
between 1966 and 1973 compared to the first phase (Bhattacherjee,
1987a, p. 57), reflecting a period of intense inter-union
rivalry. Uncertainties within the organized labour movement finally
culminated in the all-India May 1974 railway workers' strike that
shook the economy and the country.
During Mrs. Gandhi's Emergency Regime of 1975 to 1977 the right to
strike was suspended, and this is clearly reflected in time-series
strike data (Sengupta, 1992). In addition, the emergency regime
pre-empted bargaining on key issues, froze wage increases, reduced the
minimum annual bonus from 8.3 per cent to 4 per cent, and transferred
increments in the cost-of-living allowance to a compulsory savings
scheme (Rudolph and Rudolph, 1987). Two important interventions took
place during this regime. The first was an attempt by the government
to establish the National Apex Body, composed of 12 trade union
federations and 11 employer representatives, in order to encourage a
bipartite approach to industrial relations (as opposed to the earlier
tripartite approach). On the surface this seemed more responsive to
trade union preferences for voluntary collective bargaining, but this
was not the case.
The second intervention was the 1976 amendment to the Industrial
Disputes Act, that arose either from trade union pressure (unlikely
during the Emergency!) or as a populist measure, which led to
employment inflexibility: firms employing more than 300 workers had to
get (state) government permission before they could lay off
workers. Needless to say, government permission was seldom
forthcoming. However, this apparently pro-union measure had an
unexpected (at the time) effect: for the first time since
independence, the number of workdays lost to lockouts exceeded the
number of days lost to strikes (Sengupta, 1992).
During the post-Emergency regime of the Janata government
(1977-80),there was a qualitative change in the political climate but
not much rethinking in the industrial relations structure (Sengupta,
1992). A government attempt to put forward an industrial relations
bill banning strikes and lockouts in essential industries and services
met stiff opposition from most trade unions. The bill was not passed
(Sengupta, 1992). In 1977, the major central trade union
organizations in decreasing order of membership were the Indian
National Trade Union Congress, the All India Trade Union Congress, the
Hind Mazdoor Sabha, and the Centre of Indian Trade Unions
(Bhattacherjee, 1987a).
The second phase of unionism saw significant changes in collective
bargaining practices,. The Industrial Disputes Act of 1947 did not
provide for the compulsory recognition of a representative union as
the sole bargaining agent, nor did it encourage or compel parties to
bargain in good faith; more importantly, it gave no legal status to
collective bargaining agreements. However, the 1965 amendment to the
IDA gave a "higher legal footing" to agreements reached
through conciliation and adjudication. Patil (1982) describes how
employers and unions have used the 1965 amendment to transform
agreements into legal documents. First, there is a form of coalition
bargaining between multiple unions and employer in an enterprise so as
to arrive at a satisfactory settlement. Then conciliation is sought
(not after the failure of direct negotiations as in the first phase)
in order to convert the agreement into a legally binding document. The
terms of the agreement are signed in the presence of the conciliation
officer, making the contract legally binding on all parties.
The states can add their own labour legislation to the central labour
statutes, and in the early 1970s, Maharashtra, Gujerat, Rajasthan and
Madhya Pradesh enacted laws on trade union recognition. The
Maharashtra Recognition of Trade Unions and Prevention of Unfair
Labour Practices Act became effective from 1975. Failure to bargain
with the (now-defined) representative union became an unfair labour
practice under this Act. Its actual capacity to penalize is, however,
questionable (Deshpande, 1992).
In terms of wage dynamics in the urban labour markets, the second
phase of unionism was marked by significant changes as well. While
the evidence suggested declining, or at best stationary, real wages
during the first phase of unionism, Madan (1977) pointed out that the
data used in earlier studies suffered from a serious downward-bias as
they referred to a restricted category of low-paid workers. Using
wage data generated by the Annual Survey of Industries (all workers)
he found that the real wages of manufacturing workers had in fact
increased since the early 1970s; he also showed that the proportion of
low-paid workers to all workers had declined during the second phase.
This hypothesis finds further support in the papers by Tulpule and
Datta (1988; 1989) who, using Annual Survey data for 1967-84, found
evidence of substantial real wage gains since the late 1970s, with
substantial variations across industries.
It could be hypothesized that since the mid-1970s, segments within the
union movement shifted their goals from those of right to those of
interest. This distinction roughly corresponds with the value placed
by unions on centralized lobbying (rights) vis-à-vis
decentralized collective bargaining (interests). Various factors
conditioned such a shift and these became apparent during the third
phase of unionism; see below. Some of the key factors were: (a)
uneven development of firms within an industry, as well as increasing
inter-industry differentiation, meant that some sites were
considerably more profitable than others. Unions in these sectors
exploited the increased "capacity to pay" during collective
bargaining, while unions in the declining sectors had no such
opportunity; (b) workers and unions in the profitable sites were more
aware of their firm's financial performance through their informed
bargaining practices and/or through management willingness to share
this information with unions, and (c) workers in these units realized
that the leaders of many traditional party-based unions were averse to
intense decentralized bargaining, because of their party commitments
and their more national concerns.
These shifts and fractures within the organized labour movement had
serious implications for union strategies, especially in maintaining
solidarity across the entire organized labour movement. Specifically,
it become increasingly difficult for the trade union movement in India
to act as an "all encompassing" organization, especially
during the third phase of unionism. A rather pessimistic variant of
neo-institutional analysis of labour unions and collective action
(Olson, 1971) can partly explain the above difficulties. According to
this "logic of collective action", the assumption of
rationality and self-interested behaviour on the part of individuals
does not always lead to groups acting in the (collective)
interest. This is because of the "public goods" nature of this
collective interest: "though all of the members of the group
therefore have a common interest in obtaining this collective benefit,
they have no common interest in paying the cost of providing that
collective good" (Olson, 1971, p. 21). In our context, the
"cost" of obtaining collective benefits is different for the
various segments of the organized labour movement. To the extent that
these "costs" become similar across certain sectors with the
onset of liberalization (especially in sectors facing closure,
privatization and restructuring), there will be fewer barriers to the
trade union movement acting as an all encompassing organization.
Commentary
The second phase reflected an objective crisis of accumulation in
industry under the state-led industrialization regime, and a
subjective crisis of legitimacy of the "state pluralism" model
in the existing industrial relations system. This mode of regulation
caused the organized labour movement to split up. The unions of the
left had alternate voices, and employers often found them easier to
deal with in spite of their greater militancy. The Emergency Regime
represented a failed attempt by the state to impose a Latin
American-type of corporatism in labour-management relations.
Dissension occurred at the end of this second phase both within
capital and labour. In the growth sectors the labour-management
relationship increasingly turned to an informed decentralized
bargaining mode, while in the declining sectors, the government and
the large centralized trade unions found themselves enmeshed in the
"state pluralism" mode.
The analysis of Rudolph and Rudolph (1987, Ch. 10) illustrates the
fact that "organized labour has not been able to challenge India's
centrist ideology and politics, that is, to mount or support a left
class party" (p. 259). These authors characterize the Indian
industrial relations regime as one of state domination and
"involuted pluralism", using the term involution "as a
metaphor for a decline or loss of vigour that results from a
replication of units whose increase in number is accompanied by a
decline in effectiveness" (p. 269). They refer to the
multiplicity of trade unions: in 1950/51 there were 2,002 registered
trade unions, and in 1979 there were 10,021, while the average size of
unions increased only marginally (see table 2). According to Rudolph
and Rudolph, this "debilitating process" tends towards
entropy, so that even though the number of unions increases manifold,
union density keeps falling.
One might argue that the silent changes that took place in collective
bargaining practices in the growth sectors of the economy represented
attempts by both unions and capital to arrive at new governance and
institutional structures so as to minimize transaction costs. The
fractionalization of unions into smaller groups could then be
interpreted as an efficient solution to organizing workers in a
changed economic environment. In the public sector sites, economic
crises created uncertainties in previously stable internal labour
markets. In terms of industrial relations strategy, employers and
unions in a few sectors had some strategic choices at their disposal.
Towards the end of this phase it became apparent that there were
troubling union "monopoly" effects, especially in the public
sector. Public sector and government employees received considerable
fringe benefits, whereas in the private sector, unions had to bargain
hard for such benefits in a competitive economic environment.
Inflexible contract provisions, especially those relating to
deployment and retraining and to seniority rules, increased costs
substantially in the public sector. Overall, fractured union
"voices" searched for a collective mode of expression as this
second phase of unionism witnessed more industrial strife than the
other three phases both in terms of the number of disputes and the
number of workers involved (see table 3).
3.1.3 The third phase of
unionism (1980-1991)
This phase corresponds to the Sixth (1980-85) and the Seventh
(1985-90) Five-Year Plans, as well as the two Annual Plans (1990-92).
Average annual growth rates during this decade were about 5.7 per cent
but employment grew at only around 1.8 per cent (Papola, 1994).
Employment elasticities in major sectors, especially in services, fell
drastically during this time (Papola, 1994). In terms of Joshi and
Little's (1994) analysis, the third phase of unionism corresponds to
two distinct sub-periods: 1979/80 to 1984/85 and 1985/86 to 1990/91.(Endnote 9) During the first
part, the economy suffered from severe internal and external shocks:
one of the worst droughts since independence occurred in 1979, there
was trouble in the northeast, an industrial recession in 1980/81,
rising inflation and increasing oil bills. All this led to a balance
of payments crisis and then to a massive IMF loan. In May 1984, India
terminated the programme after drawing SDR 3.9 billion (Joshi and
Little, 1994, p. 60). This period was also turbulent on the political
front with Mrs. Gandhi's return to power in 1980, the assault on the
Golden Temple in Amritsar, Mrs. Ghandi's assassination in October
1984 and the landslide victory of the Congress Party with her son
Rajiv as Prime Minister.
The second part of this phase is associated with Rajiv Gandhi's
economic liberalization measures. The economy moved away from import
substitution towards strategies that encouraged export promotion and
domestic competition. This was bought about by partial deregulation,
financial liberalization, exchange rate policy, taxation, and export
incentives (Joshi and Little, 1994, p. 62).(Endnote 10) After 1988 the country
experienced severe unrest. The 1990 Gulf crisis was followed by
economic recession and political turmoil.
India was now facing a full-scale macroeconomic crisis. "Agreement
was reached with the IMF in January 1991 on a loan of $1.8 billion,
partly out of the Compensatory Financing Facility (to offset increased
oil imports) and partly as a first credit tranche standby" (Joshi
and Little, 1994, p. 66).
The macroeconomic changes during this phase had a profound effect on
the political economy of trade unionism and labour markets, as well as
on the structure of industrial relations. On the union front, this
phase started with a massive public sector strike in Bangalore during
1980/81 which involved giant public enterprises such as Hindustan
Machine Tools, Hindustan Aeronautics Limited, Electronics Corporation
of India, and Indian Telephone Industries.
The event that characterized the first part of this third phase was
the famous, and much studied, Mumbai textile strike of 1982 (see
Patankar, 1981; Pendse, 1981; Bhattacherjee, 1988; 1989; Van Wersch,
1992). This started as a wage and bonus issue in a few mills in
late-1981, and soon developed into an industry-wide stoppage that
ultimately became the longest strike in post-independence labour
history. The basic cause was disquiet among the rank and file about
the 1947 Bombay Industrial Relations Act, which had imposed an
industry-wide bargaining structure with an unrepresentative union
(affiliated to the Indian National Trade Union Congress) as the sole
bargaining agent of workers. As a result of the internal
differentiation within the mills which took place during the 1970s,
workers wanted more control over their labour market- and industrial
relations outcomes at the level of the individual mill. They
approached Dr. Datta Samant to lead their struggle: his main project
was to form and lead an "independent" trade union movement in
Western India.
The textile strike ended in a whimper late in 1983: many workers
returned to their villages, their lives ruined, employers restructured
their mills in the advanced textile sector, and the credibility of the
government-installed union in the industry declined to levels from
which it could never recover (Bhattacherjee, 1988). Evidence from the
immediate post-strike period seems to suggest that workers and unions,
at least in the profitable mills, negotiated their own decentralized
bargaining agreements (Bhattacherjee, 1989; Van Wersch, 1992). After
Datta Samant formed the Kamgar Aghadi Party and won a few
seats in Parliament in 1984, many commentators felt that this was a
new and encouraging beginning for the organized labour movement in
India.(Endnote 11)
Another important feature of this third phase was the proliferation of
"independent" unions operating in the major industrial centres
and competing with the traditional party-affiliated trade unions (both
of the Congress and of the Left). In Mumbai, for example, the decline
of the Left unions is partly attributable to their general opposition
to intense decentralized bargaining (Pendse, 1981). Segmented and
uneven developments in the industrial sector tied workers' earnings to
the fortunes of the plant in which they were employed. An analysis of
plant-level contracts from the Greater Mumbai-Thane industrial
corridor revealed that, ceteris paribus, the
"independent" unions delivered a higher wage and fringe
package than did the affiliated unions at the beginning of this third
phase (Bhattacherjee, 1987b). In a number of multinationals, it was
found that workers with their "independent" unions exerted
considerable control over the labour relations process, often more
than their counterparts in the host country (see the example of
Phillips in Banaji and Hensman, 1990).
In the late 1970s there was a phenomenal rise in the number of
disputes led by unaffiliated unions and the importance of politically
affiliated unions declined (Bhattacherjee, 1987a, p. 57). The ratio
of registered unions that submit returns about their membership size
to the total number of registered unions fell sharply from 60 per cent
in 1962 to 21 per cent in 1974 to 13 per cent in 1982 (Bhattacherjee
and Datta Chaudhuri, 1994a, p. 70). This would support the hypothesis
of the rise of "independent" unionism, if the total number of
registered unions that submit returns proxies the traditional
party-affiliated trade unions.(Endnote 12) By 1989 the Labour Ministry
listed the following union organizations in their registry: Indian
National Trade Union Congress, All India Trade Union Congress, Centre
of Indian Trade Unions, Hind Mazdoor Singh, the Bharatiya Mazdoor
Sabha (BMS, affiliated to the BJP), the Hind Mazdoor Kamgar
Party, United Trade Union Congress (UTUC), United Trade Union
Congress Lenin Sarani, National Labour Organization, and a number of
small independent unions.
Finally, this phase was marked by increasing inter-regional,
inter-state, and inter-city variations in the nature of
labour-management relations.(Endnote
13) In a study of Bombay, Calcutta, Madras and
Bangalore, Ramaswamy (1988) points to significant inter-city
differences in the texture of labour-management relationships. He
writes (1988, p.17): "The driving force of the Bombay labour
movement are union leaders who disclaim allegiance to political
parties and their trade union federations. What we find here is the
most evolved Indian version of business trade unionism", and
"the city has witnessed the steady decline, if not eclipse into
oblivion, of ideological trade unionism". This clearly has
something to do with the fact that private and multinational firms
dominate Mumbai's urban economy. As Ramaswamy puts it: "there is
an organic linkage between the buccaneering spirit of Mumbai unions
and the eclecticism and adaptability of private enterprise".
In sharp contrast is the case of Calcutta, where a highly politicized
industrial relations regime prevails with the dominant trade union
federation (the CITU) under the close watch of the dominant political
party (the CPI-M). This has created considerable inflexibilities for
management, and has partly prohibited the growth of independent trade
unionism. Bangalore, a city where both private and public sector
enterprises thrive, especially those in the information technology
industry, has witnessed the rise of plant and firm-based unions (as in
Mumbai). Inter-city differences, attributable no doubt to different
political, social, and urban histories, emphatically suggest the
inherent difficulties in trying to generalize about an
"Indian" labour relations system. With the passing of time,
especially with the onset of the fourth phase (see below), attempts at
this kind of generalization will become more and more difficult.
Changes in union structure, together with macroeconomic developments,
considerably affected both employment and the wage structure. Between
1980/81 and 1988/89, while employment growth declined, the
capital-labour ratio and labour productivity increased by 8 per cent
and 7.5 per cent per year respectively (Ahluwalia, 1992). According to
Ghose (1992, p. 95), "The most striking fact is that the 80s have
been the best decade in terms of economic growth but the worst decade
in terms of employment generation". Moreover, employment growth
decelerated in all sectors of the economy and open unemployment
increased in the 1980s (Ghose, 1992). The search for labour market
flexibility in Indian manufacturing led labour-intensive firms and
those engaged in the production of consumer non-durables to
subcontract and outsource their production to the unorganized sectors
(Ramaswamy, 1999).
Unions in the organized and more profitable sectors (often
"independent" unions), managed to secure part of these
productivity increases through militant bargaining and/or through
productivity bargains that contained effective incentive
structures. This resulted in slower employment growth. In the
relatively unorganized and less profitable sites, workers and unions
lost out. While formal sector employment as a percentage of total
employment in manufacturing fell from 24.5 per cent in 1972/73 to 17.4
per cent in 1987/88, real wages of workers and "other
employees" in organized manufacturing increased at a rate of 5.8
per cent and 4.1 per cent between 1983 and 1986 respectively, whereas
low-paid workers suffered declining real wages (Ghose, 1992, p. 97).
As the union wage effect increased significantly in the profitable
sites (especially in consumer non-durables) during this phase,
employers cut back on hiring and started retrenchment, increasing the
capital-labour ratio which in turn increased labour productivity.
Thus, according to this scenario, the faster growth of real wages in
the 1980s played a role in slowing employment creation (Ahluwalia,
1992).
Bhattacherjee and Datta Chaudhuri (1994b) found that: (a) in the
high-paid sector, real wages increased after the late 1970s and there
were wage returns from striking, (b) in the low-paid sector, real
wages declined after the early 1980s, and employers could lower wages
by imposing lockouts; and (c) in terms of union structure, low-paid
workers gain as unions submitting returns (proxy for traditional
unions) increase their dominance within the union movement, whereas,
high paid workers gain as registered unions not submitting returns
(proxy for plant-specific unions) increase their dominance. The
traditional unions predominant in the older industries provided
overall protection to their members as long as these industries grew.
As they declined, and as plant-specific unions reaped returns in the
high-paid sector, workers in the low-paid sector "became more
vulnerable to competitive forces and could no longer count on the
traditional 'wage-welfare' functions provided by the party-based
unions. Workers in this segment will find it difficult to form strong
plant-specific unions due to increasing instability in their product
markets" (Bhattacherjee and Datta Chaudhuri, 1994b, p. 459).(Endnote 14)
Jose (1992) examined earnings, employment, and productivity trends for
19 industry groups for the period 1970/71 to 1987/88. His findings
were: (a) whereas the 1970s are associated with employment growth in
both high and low wage sectors and with stagnant and even declining
productivity levels, the 1980s are associated with slower employment
growth with rising productivity levels, especially in the high wage
sectors; (b) higher productivity brought about the (modest 2-3 per
cent per year) increase in real earnings in the high-wage sectors.
These findings seem to fit with the characterization of different
types of union dominating these two labour markets since the early
1980s. Jose (1992) maintains that technological change led to the rise
in wages and productivity, whereas subsequent analysts inverted the
hypothesis to argue that union militancy and higher wages resulted in
technological change that subsequently led to a decline in employment.
Labour researchers towards the end of this third phase focused on
employment inflexibilities embedded in the Industrial Disputes Act
(see Mathur, 1992). The 1982 amendment of the Industrial Disputes Act
provided that a firm employing more than 100 workers (reduced from
>300) needed permission from the state government to lay-off or
retrench workers. Fallon and Lucas (1991) showed how employment would
have been higher in several sectors without the 1976 and 1982
amendments. Mathur (1992) recommended that the sections pertaining to
permission for lay-off, retrenchment or closure be deleted from the
Act.
To remedy the limitations of the Industrial Disputes Act and the Trade
Union Act, from both the union and the employer point of view, a
number of changes were proposed in the Trade Unions and Industrial
Disputes (Amendment) Bill, 1988 (Mathur, 1992). The proposed changes
would reduce the fragmentation and multiplicity of unions, clearly
define the bargaining agent by providing for a secret ballot, promote
internal leadership, create state-level industrial tribunals, force
employers to set up comprehensive bargaining councils to facilitate
internal grievance settlement, and so on. After considerable debate
however the bill was rejected because of controversy over the
definition of "industry" (Mathur, 1992, p. 50).
Commentary
The "independent" unions arose in Western India from within
the rank and file, throwing up their own shopfloor leaders, and
initially encountering considerable hostility from management due to
their militant bargaining strategies.These unions arose primarily as a
result of dissatisfaction with the bargaining weakness of the
traditional unions at enterprise level.
One way to distinguish between unions is to look at the arguments
which they emphasize at micro level (Bhattacherjee and Datta
Chaudhuri, 1994b). Given the level of demand for organized labour,
unions, like employers, face a wage-employment trade-off during
contract negotiations. The situation that prevailed during the third
phase, and continues to prevail, can be described in the following
way. There are two types of union: those that are
"altruistic" and those that are "selfish". Given a
choice between wage increases and an increase in employment, the
"altruistic" unions choose the latter, as membership is the
crucial argument to be maximized; consequently, their bargaining
strength is positively related to their size. The large and
established national trade union federations that are typically
affiliated to political parties, display this type of union behaviour.
On the other hand, "selfish" unions are interested in
maximizing the wages of those already employed in a particular
enterprise, and confronted with the trade-off, they opt for wage
increases. In this case, small is powerful. The so-called
"independent" unions seem to approximate the latter. It is
clear why the "selfish" unions would be more likely to sign
productivity bargains than the "altruistic" unions; for the
latter, productivity bargains cut at the source of their strength,
i.e., growing union membership. While at micro level, in profitable
sites, bilateral collective bargaining with "selfish" unions
seems to have generated efficient and cooperative outcomes, at macro
level, the trade union "movement" in a democracy has to be an
all-encompassing organization. Here lies the difficulty in
formulating a fair but efficient industrial relations policy: what is
efficient at the micro level is not fair at the macro level
(Bhattacherjee, 1996).
In terms of the "monopoly versus collective voice" framework,
labour market evidence from the third phase of unionism seems to
suggest that some monopoly effects dominated the collective voice, and
that the proliferation of "selfish" unions and their
microeconomic success may have had a negative effect on unorganized
labour markets. In the private corporate sector, firms attempted
"efficiency wage" strategies, usually with the cooperation of
unions, but often changing the nature of plant or firm-level unions in
the process. In public-sector internal labour markets, unions often
became involved in unproductive activities while managing these
enterprises. The importance of concepts such as internal governance
structures of trade unions and their effects on efficiency and
fairness became increasingly relevant during this phase of unionism.
In terms of industrial relations strategy, the actors had more options
than before and one could even suggest that some segments operated
their own strategy, insulated from outside forces. Thus, effective
"gainsharing" resulted from efficient bargaining in some
sectors, whereas in the unorganized sectors, a free market regime
prevailed. Once more, attempts at serious reform of industrial
relations law came to a predictable grinding halt.(Endnote 15)
3.1.4 The fourth phase of
unionism (1992-2000)
In June 1991, the ruling minority government decided to adopt
the World Bank-IMF stabilization and structural adjustment
programme.(Endnote 16)
"In July 1991 the rupee was devalued twice, quotas on the import
of intermediate and capital goods were reduced, tariffs were brought
down, the state monopoly on exports and imports was ended and a
statement on industrial policy was presented along with the Union
Budget, which was aimed at reducing the fiscal deficit by two and a
half percentage points" (Mathur, 1993, p. 333). The fourth phase
of unionism more or less corresponds to the Eighth (1992-97) and the
Ninth (1997-2002) Five-Year Plans.
According to Nagaraj (1997, p. 2870) "On average, the Indian
economy grew at 5.3 per cent during the first five years of the
reforms (1992-96), compared to 5.9 per cent during 1986-91". The
tertiary sector grew fastest in the 1990s, at about 6.8 per cent per
year. The economy has become considerably more "open" than
ever before. There was some apprehension that government expenditure
in the social sector would decline significantly, but Nagaraj (1997)
found that social spending, averaged over four years since the
reforms, did not suffer; most of the cuts made in defense and economic
services. Again, contrary to expectations, investment performance in
India actually improved after the reforms, with private corporate
business emerging as the economy's "leading sector". However,
in terms of industrial growth performance, "the manufacturing
growth rate since the reforms is lower and its composition is
uneven" (1997, p. 2875). Even though public investment had
witnessed deep cuts since the reform, "public sector output growth
and profitability improved" suggesting better resource
utilization. Nagaraj concludes: "In sum, the good news (so far) is
that there is no major, unqualified, bad news".
Transnational corporations, as expected, have reacted very favourably
to the new economic policy. Chaudhuri (1995) examines the mechanisms
through which transnational corporations have achieved entry and
growth: through the ousting of Indian partners, through extensive
mergers and acquisitions, and through expansion and fresh entry. The
gross inflow of foreign direct investment rose from Rs.5.3 billion in
1991 to Rs.141.9 billion in 1994 (US$1 is approximately Rs.0.44), and
although Chaudhuri is sceptical about the prospects of this investment
leading to export-oriented growth in India, it is expected to generate
some employment.
If the 1995-96 period was a slowdown, and 1996-97 was a year of
"industrial recession and political uncertainty", the year
1997-98 can be described as an "elusive economic recovery"
with a "hesitant government".(Endnote 17) A whole range of issues on the
economic reform agenda remain incomplete: infrastructure development,
greater transparency in investment procedures, restoration of business
confidence, review of import duties, further banking sector reforms,
and most important, public sector and labour market reforms.
The available data seem to suggest that economic reform has led to an
increase in rural poverty and a decline in urban poverty; in fact,
urban poverty was lower in 1993-94 than in any pre-reform year (Sen,
1996). Deshpande and Deshpande (1996) found that although the initial
stabilization years "took some toll of organized manufacturing
employment", subsequent structural adjustment led to employment
growth at around 2.3 per cent between 1992/93 and 1994/95. If this
rate continues for the next few years, "employment in the factory
sector would be about 12 per cent higher at the turn of the century
than in 1990/91" (1996, p. 18). In terms of the structure of
employment, these authors found that in some sectors the employment
share increased after the reforms (textiles, transport equipment,
chemicals, beverages, metal products) while in others the employment
share decreased (machinery).
Mundle (1992) presented employment and unemployment projections under
"high" and "low" growth scenarios taking into account
employment elasticities and labour force participation rates. Even
under the most optimistic scenario in the private sector, given
declining employment elasticities in organized manufacturing and the
unlikely expansion of employment in the public sector, it is quite
evident that a "large majority of the nearly 80 million persons
who will join the labour force during 1999-2000 will have to find work
as self-employed or casual workers" (Visaria and Minhas, 1991,
p. 978). In terms of the impact of economic reforms on women workers,
Deshpande and Deshpande (1992) believe that female unemployment may go
down but the openings available will be low-wage jobs in secondary
labour markets. In the light of the above, it seems imperative to
expand the existing public employment schemes. However, the most
appropriate strategy for a predominantly agrarian economy such as
India must be to raise labour force participation rates and shift the
workforce away from agriculture into more productive sectors so as to
generate large economy-wide productivity gains (Bhaduri, 1993).
One of the main objectives of the economic reform package is the
restructuring of unprofitable public sector enterprises.(Endnote 18) These enterprises
are free to reduce their workforce through voluntary retirement
schemes (VRS) assisted by the national renewal fund (NRF) instituted
by the government, and by amendments to the Sick Industrial Companies
Act 1985. The strengthening of the Board for Industrial and Financial
Reconstruction considerably facilitated this process (Mathur, 1993).
The objectives of the NRF were to provide assistance to cover the
costs of retraining and redeployment made necessary by modernization,
technological upgrading, industrial restructuring, and possible
closure. In 1993-94, Rupees 7 billion (US$1 = approx. Rs0.44) were
allocated to the VRS in the central public sector enterprises; nearly
Rupees 4.9 billion was allocated to the textile sector alone
(Muralidhar, 1993).
While recruitment was all but frozen (especially at lower levels), the
government also froze the centralized wage bargaining process for a
few years after 1992. It later opened the negotiation process and
attempted to decentralize bargaining by announcing that any wage
increases would have to be absorbed by the specific enterprise as
these could no longer be passed on to the final price. In other words,
the new policy clearly stated that any additional wage burden would
not receive budgetary support (Venkataratnam, 1996).
The need for tripartite consultation was clearly felt during the early
years and many meetings took place. Mathur (1993) documents the
experience of consultation during the early phase of structural
adjustment in India (1990-92), and suggests that although the
government partly diffused possible tension through its consultative
approach, unions had "serious misgivings about the adequacy of
consultation at (the) industrial or enterprise level" (p. 344).
Labour commentators have found that the centralized and traditional
union structures often fall short of worker expectations, and in many
instances, they are giving way to independent and decentralized union
structures (Davala, 1992; Muralidhar, 1994). However, this (current)
fourth phase has witnessed the growth of the Bharatiya Mazdoor Sangh,
affiliated to the Bharatiya Janata Party. In the state of
Maharashtra, the trade union movement has become quite volatile since
the locally based Shiv Sena party and its affiliated union, the
Bharatiya Mazdoor Sena, made deep inroads.
During this phase the public has become acutely aware (largely through
the print and visual media) that trade unions represent a declining
"sectional interest group". Bhaduri and Nayyar (1996, p. 139)
point this out in no uncertain terms: "The government also needs
to protect consumers against sectional interests of many
unrepresentative trade unions. While the trade union rights of
workers must also be respected in any democracy, the government must
also ensure, perhaps through secret ballot, that no unrepresentative
union harasses ordinary consumers". They go on to add:
"…recognition of workers' rights must go with appropriate
regulations for recognizing these rights. All such rules of the game
need to be set transparently, and without partisanship".
On 10 January 1999 the government announced the second National Labour
Commission (the first NLC was set up 30 years ago). The terms of
reference lay down that the commission should suggest rationalization
of existing labour laws in the organized sector and recommend umbrella
legislation to ensure minimum protection for unorganized workers. The
commission has a two-year term and is made up of representatives from
government, trade unions and industry. Trade unions feel that workers
have little protection from the whims of errant management, and that
any alteration in the law would only add to managerial power. For
example, the proposal to relax the law on contract labour in order to
generate more jobs on contract for the unorganized sector is
interpreted by the unions as a move to undercut permanent unionized
jobs. More recently, proposed changes in the Industrial Disputes Act
will make it difficult for trade unions to call wildcat strikes and
the amendments will dilute the need for employers to have government
approval for a lockout. On the other hand, they give the tribunals
more power to penalize errant employers.
The present government dissolved the National Renewal Fund and
entrusted the corpus to the Ministry of Industry. The money in the
fund will now be given to public sector enterprises directly by the
Ministry. The government hopes to monitor the use of funds more
effectively by not involving the administrative departments that
control these enterprises. More recently, the government has
announced that it will develop a comprehensive strategy to deal with
unprofitable public enterprises and "hammer out a mechanism which
makes it easier to close chronically sick units". Officials in
the Ministry of Finance announced that more funds have to be pumped
into the voluntary retirement schemes so that workers can be retrained
and redeployed in viable public sector units.(Endnote 19)
Commentary
In terms of labour market and industrial relations reforms, the
continuation of economic liberalization would undoubtedly lead to more
employment flexibility, greater decentralization in bargaining
structures (especially in public enterprises) and hence less
government intervention in the bargaining process, fewer strikes, and
a possible halt to the fragmentation of the union movement. On the
positive side, this could mean more employment and a more effective
union voice at both micro- and macro-level, with industrial pluralism
being strengthened. On the negative side, the proposed reforms could
increase managerial power and accelerate the growth of the non-union
sector, leading to a decline in the power of organized labour. At
microeconomic level, unions of all political hues are cooperating with
management in the restructuring process (often because they have no
choice). However, at the macro-level, the organized labour movement is
generally extremely critical of globalization and reform. From a
strategic viewpoint, trade union federations of different political
affiliations will have to forge a united front at the macro-level to
ensure their continuing growth as "all-encompassing"
organizations. This means organizing non-union workers.
Differences within the centralized trade unions, political parties,
and state governments have indefinitely delayed the passage of
industrial relations reforms. The lack of consensus and political
instability at the centre since 1992 (several coalition governments
have failed to complete their full term), mean a lack of political
will to carry out these reforms. A worrying consequence of the
inability to reach a national consensus on labour market reform is the
future effect on regional labour markets and labour relations in
general of heightened inter-state competition to attract foreign and
local capital. In the absence of national reforms, various states may
attempt to level down their labour market institutions by offering
incentives to investment. The latter will have a profound effect on
regional variations in labour standards. As these divergent trends
will make it increasingly difficult for the centralized trade union
federations to act at national level, it is in their immediate
interest to press for industrial relations reform.
3.2 The issues
The above discussion on the four phases of Indian trade unionism
sketched out the interaction between changes in the overall economy
and their effects on the labour market and on industrial relations. In
this section we examine several issues that arise from the discussion
and speculate on trends in the near future. These issues are:
unionization and employment; union structure and union density; wages
and working conditions; collective bargaining; industrial conflict;
labour-management relations; inter-state variations; unionization and
women workers; and the changing public perception of trade unions.
3.2.1 Unionization and
employment
Declining employment elasticities imply that more output is
attained with less employment. This could be due to the fact that
employers are investing in more capital-intensive technologies, and
that there has been a considerable amount of labour shedding in the
private and public-sector enterprises since the mid-1980s. Unions can
affect these employment elasticities by resisting technological change
that increases the possibility of substituting between capital and
labour and by limiting the availability of goods and services that
compete with the output of unionized firms. In addition, union
bargaining power varies indirectly with labour's share in total costs:
unions are more powerful in relatively more capital-intensive firms
and industries, as the demand for labour is relatively inelastic
compared to labour-intensive sectors. Employers in capital-intensive
firms find it much easier to meet union wage demands compared to
employers in labour-intensive firms. Finally, it is in the interest
of unions to raise the price of other inputs, particularly non-union
labour, as this increases the cost of switching from union to
non-union labour (see Borjas, 1996, pp. 126-127).
To illustrate the usefulness of the above, consider the following. In
the current scenario, labour and unions in the more labour-intensive
sectors in India face considerably more uncertain and insecure times
than their counterparts in more capital-intensive sectors. Several
firms in the textile and jute industries are near closure. On the
other hand, the majority of plant-based "independent" unions
are located in more capital-intensive industries, and union bargaining
power in several public sector sites (such as transportation and
banking) is high due to its specific market characteristics defined by
state monopoly. In some states, such as in Kerala and West Bengal,
progressive unions in conjunction with their state governments have
improved the wages and working conditions of agricultural and
unorganized workers, thereby curtailing the growth of income
inequalities within the workforce as a whole.
Over time, average annual growth rates in GDP have outstripped average
annual growth rates in employment (table 4) and employment
elasticities in major sectors have fallen (table 5). Table 1 shows
the level of employment in the private and public sectors over the
"four phases of unionism". This table clearly shows the
following: in the first phase, public sector employment increased
sharply and private sector employment increased marginally; during the
second phase, public sector employment increased rapidly, whereas
private sector employment remained sluggish; during the third phase,
employment growth in both sectors sharply tapered off; and during the
first few years of the fourth phase, growth in both sectors remained
nearly static.
Table 6 presents a sectoral distribution of employment in the formal
economy. We note two trends: since the third phase, growth in
employment in manufacturing, both in the public and private sectors,
has remained virtually stagnant; however, during the third phase,
employment increased in public services. We also observe the
phenomenal growth in employment in services (especially in the public
sector) relative to manufacturing. Finally, except in manufacturing,
the public sector continued to be the dominant employer in the
organized economy. Table 7 shows a sector-wise ranking of the number
and membership of trade unions that register and submit returns over
the four phases of unionism. We observe that: (a) manufacturing leads
in the number of unions and membership size; (b) construction lags
behind most other sectors.
Given that the macro data on employment and unionization in India are
riddled with problems and contain errors of omission, detailed case
studies of specific industries and regions have revealed significantly
different trends. The Friedrich Ebert Stiftung study (Davala,
1992) is an example. It covers tea plantations and the jute industry
in West Bengal, the coal sector, ports and docks, the engineering
industries of Andhra Pradesh and West Bengal, the power sector in
Andhra Pradesh, and the chemical and pharmaceutical industry in
Maharashtra. Although the study shows a fair number of inter-industry
and regional variations, there were some striking similarities. The
trend everywhere was a downsizing of permanent employment and the
proliferation of contract, temporary, and casual jobs. There were very
low rates of unionization of contract and casual labour, with the
unions being more sensitive to the plight of such workers in the newer
industries.
(Endnote 20)
In the state of Maharashtra, permanent workers and their unions in the
chemical and pharmaceutical industries have realized that their
well-being is ultimately tied to their fellow workers in the
"reserve army of labour". The study found that unions
organize on an industry- and/or region-wide basis in the older
industrial sectors, but the enterprise becomes the unit of
organization in the newer industries. This pattern corresponds with
the prevalent bargaining structure (i.e., industry- and region-wide in
the older industries, and plant-level in the newer industries). As
Ramaswamy concludes in this study (Davala, 1992, p. 231):
The common thread running through most of these variations is the
desire of workers to gain greater control over their unions. This
might well be the case in the older industries as well, but the
structure of trade unionism does not permit much scope for the
expression of these aspirations. In the newer industries, on the
other hand, trade union structure itself appears to have been
influenced by this fundamental force.
The "market friendly" views of the relationship between
unionization and employment in India, especially during the third and
fourth phase, was elaborated earlier, but needs to be emphasized in
this section as well. The "monopoly effects" of trade unions,
together with inflexible labour laws, have enabled employers to move
up their demand curves and have practically frozen employment growth
in permanent unionized jobs. Due to union wage mark-ups, employers
have increased the capital intensity of production, thereby raising
productivity. But this route can only lead to jobless growth, clearly
a sub-optimal outcome in a labour surplus economy. Those who oppose
this view point out that wage increases took place not because of
union power but largely because of an intensification of the labour
process resulting from a decline in union power. A disaggregated
analysis probably comes closest to reality: in the more prosperous
sectors, with low elasticities of labour demand, "selfish"
plant-specific unions managed to extract generous wage increases; in
the less prosperous sectors, largely in the public sector,
"altruistic" unions affiliated to political parties have had
little success with centralized bargaining procedures in unstable
product markets.
In the buoyant sectors of production, even before 1991, employers have
managed to execute viable exit policies through generous Voluntary
Retirement Schemes, with the cooperation of enterprise-based unions.
In these largely private sector sites, "bringing the union in"
has clearly paid dividends in terms of generating "strongly
efficient contracts" (that is, when the labour contract leads a
unionized firm to hire the competitive level of employment). In the
public sector, however, exit schemes (available through the National
Renewal Fund) have few individual takers or else they face union
resistance at national level. The general secretary of the All India
Bank Employees' Association says, "We will resist any attempt to
introduce a VRS. As far as we are concerned, job security is more
important than wage revision".(Endnote 21)
The practice of "featherbedding" (employing more people than
required) in a whole range of public enterprises is no longer
financially viable. The union movement as a whole, especially the
large centralized and industry-wide public sector unions, may benefit
more from unionizing the unorganized than from attempting to preserve
unproductive jobs.
3.2.2 Union structure and union
density
The number of registered unions increased from 3,766 in 1950/51 to
55,784 in 1993, whereas the average size of those that submitted
returns decreased from 577 to 460 during the same period (see table
2). As stated earlier, not all registered trade unions submit returns
on their membership. If we assume that the registered unions which
submit returns are the large, established politically-affiliated
unions with the organizational resources to engage in this process,
whereas the registered unions that do not submit returns are the
plant-based independent unions, then movements in the fifth column of
table 2 (percentage of unions submitting returns to total registered
unions) makes for an interesting interpretation. It appears that the
centralized unions dominated during the first phase, lost ground
during the second phase, and then sharply declined during the third
phase, dropping to an all-time low of only 12 per cent in 1993.
Although this is only one possible reading of the data, several
detailed case studies have also pointed to these movements in union
structure (Ramswamy, 1988; Davala, 1992).
To illustrate the above with some region-specific examples, consider
the following: (a) in the jute industry in and around Calcutta, union
membership for each of the major unions declined with a fall in the
proportion of permanent workers, even though "a large number of
small, ultra-left and even unaffiliated unions have emerged during the
last decade" (Sen, 1992, p. 48); (b) in the coal mines in Eastern
India, the independent unions represent more than a quarter of the
total workforce (Sen, 1992, p. 71); (c) in the state of Andhra
Pradesh, "the emergence and growth of non-affiliated unions is
perhaps one of the most striking features of the trade union scenario
in the engineering industry during the last decade" (Guptan, 1992,
p. 124); and (d) more than 50 per cent of the unions in the chemical
and pharmaceutical industries in the state of Maharashtra are
unaffiliated independent unions (Davala, 1992, p. 210). The fourth
phase is also associated with the sudden rise of the Bharatiya
Mazdoor Sabham, especially in those states governed by the
Bharatiya Janata Party.
The decentralized independent unions have in some instances attempted
to generate firm-wide agreements but they have been unsuccessful
because of considerable employer resistance at firm level. Some recent
commentators have suggested that these unions have been on the
defensive ever since the reforms. This is partly because they lost
staff through voluntary retirement schemes; it was also due to the
strategies of multinationals which severely cut back on permanent
unionized employment. Other factors were the setting up of non-union
facilities at new sites and the practice of subcontracting work to the
informal sector (Banaji and Hensman, 1995; Noronha, 1996).
3.2.3 Wages and working
conditions
Table 8 provides data on the movement of the consumer price index for
industrial workers and urban non-manual employees across the four
phases of unionism. Tables 9 and 10 provide some data on the movement
of nominal (a general index for 12 industries) and real wage rates (in
organized manufacturing).
Standard neoclassical economic theory would argue that increased
global trade raises the earnings of unskilled workers relative to
those of skilled workers in a country such as India, which has
unlimited supplies of the former. This implies that India's exports
are largely unskilled labour-intensive products. Nambiar et
al. (1999) found that wage disparity for the period 1980/81 to 1992/93
increased but only marginally. In addition, they found that the
disparity rises from less skill-intensive to more skill-intensive
sectors. To the extent that the union voice reduces earnings
inequality within the unionized workforce, employers, especially in
the private sector, have "manufactured consent" with the
unions in setting up ingenious pay incentive systems.
Wage determination in the organized economy varies significantly
between the private and the public sector (Datta Chaudhuri, 1996;
Anant and Sundaram, 1998). In the private corporate sector, where
collective bargaining largely takes place at enterprise level, unions
that are willing to accept some risk have benefited from a form of
gainsharing by agreeing to tie a significant part of the monthly pay
to incentives. The incentive structures are designed to generate
cooperative behaviour at the departmental, plant and firm level.
Risk-averse unions, usually more concerned with employment growth than
with members' wages have resisted management attempts to impose such
systems.
In many of the older sectors, such as tea plantations and jute in
Eastern India and textiles in Western India, industry-wide bargaining
is the institutional norm. With the advent of economic
liberalization, this bargaining structure will be under pressure to
decentralize some of the outcomes as inter-plant and inter-firm
differences become wider (see 3.2.4 below). Similar decentralizing
pressures will be felt increasingly in public sector industries, even
though the Bureau of Public Enterprises "sends guidelines for wage
settlement to all administrative ministries, setting down norms to be
followed in determining basic salaries and the various categories of
benefits for different classes of employees" (Datta Chaudhuri,
1996, p. 18). In Coal India, for example, employees in the better-off
units feel that their earnings could increase substantially if they
were linked more closely to productivity at the unit level.
Centralized public sector unions will have to come to terms with these
decentralized union "voices".
Salaries and benefits for central government employees in public
administration, academic institutions, posts and telegraph, etc., are
determined in detail by the Pay Commissions which are periodically set
up by the government.(Endnote
22) As Datta Chaudhuri (1996, p. 18) puts it: "The award
of the Pay Commission for the Central Government employees becomes the
reference point for wage determination in the rest of the public
sector." The Pay Commission is the object of considerable lobbying
by various unions and employees' associations prior to and during the
deliberations.
The recommendations of the Fifth Central Pay Commission have been
implemented and employees in the central and state governments have
seen their incomes rise substantially. If it is true that the
disparity between the average salary of government employees and per
capita income is far higher in India than in most other countries,(Endnote 23) the public
clearly need to see vast improvements in productivity in this sector
given the fairly high additional cost involved in delivering the pay
recommendations (Joseph, 1997). The All India Federation of College
Teachers' Organizations could, for example, take a lead in
self-monitoring their constituency so as to impose work norms and
discipline. There are already many rules to deal with employees who
do not work and/or who are late; applying these rules occasionally
will send strong signals to both employees and to the public (Joseph,
1997).
Industrial accident rates in India, both fatal and non-fatal, are
extremely high compared to most countries. While it is true that the
occupational health and safety monitoring agencies are weak, it is
also the case that unions can intervene significantly more in this
area than they are presently doing. Often, workers demand higher
wages for increased safety measures during contract deliberations.(Endnote 24) But there are
other examples where unions have been closely involved in occupational
health and safety matters. One such case is the Occupational Health
and Safety Centre that operates out of two union offices in Central
Mumbai and was set up largely due to the inefficiencies of the
Employees' State Insurance (ESI) Scheme. Among its many achievements,
the Centre was able to get the ESI medical board to recognize and
compensate mill workers suffering from occupational bysinosis in 1994.
The linking of minimum labour standards and trade agreements, i.e. the
"social clause", has generated considerable debate and
discussion among trade unions and labour commentators (FES-IIRA, 1996;
Hensman, 1996; Bhattacherjee, 1997). There are various economic
arguments in favour of the imposition of international labour
standards (ILS). To the extent that labour markets in developing
countries are beset with imperfect and asymmetric information (for
example relating to industrial safety), ILS may level up labour market
institutions to correct for market failures of this type. ILS can be
used as a redistributive mechanism if the government feels that the
market- determined income distribution profile is skewed towards the
more skilled workers in relatively protected environments. Trade
unions in India interpret this imposed link as a disguised form of
protectionism (for the various trade union views, see FES-IIRA, 1996,
and Hensman, 1996). This argument leads to the same outcome as those
put forward by the 'comparative advantage' trade theorists that the
imposition of ILS will lead to a reduction in the net gains from
trade, and therefore individual countries should decide on their own
labour standards. But surely one has to question this simple view.
Why is it that countries with relatively abundant and cheap labour
find it difficult to compete in international markets, except in those
sectors that have (relatively) lower labour standards? Clearly, this
kind of participation in global trade, where inferior labour standards
are the "comparative advantage" is unlikely to lead to social
progress. Since it is not enough to wait for sustained economic
growth to upgrade domestic labour standards, the unions need to
forcefully generate demands, both from above and below, for
improvements in working conditions. Hensman (1996) spells out an
agenda for trade unionists and NGOs that strongly believe that labour
standards in India have to be substantially improved, perhaps even
through trade links and other forms of international pressure.
3.2.4 Collective
bargaining
Two critical aspects of the collective bargaining system are an
expansion of the coverage and scope of long-term agreements and the
increasing pressure for decentralized bargaining. These tendencies
originated during the third phase of unionism and became acute during
the post-reform fourth phase. The restructuring agreements cover
(among other things): ban on recruitment, job transfers to
non-bargainable category, introduction of parallel production,
automation and flexibility, transfer of production to subcontracted
units, introduction of voluntary retirement schemes, transfer of
permanent jobs to contract/temporary workers, merger of units, and a
host of other shopfloor restructuring provisions (Venkataratnam,
1996). Concession bargaining in several units has led to job and wage
cuts, a freeze on cost-of-living allowances, and suspension of
industrial action for a period of five years. While the above
suggests that management has had the upper hand in recent years,
Venkataratnam (1996) also lists some "unusual" clauses that
suggest a positive union "collective voice" effect: linking
allowances such as house rent and children's education to attendance,
permitting pregnant women to refuse to work on computer terminals,
voluntary retirement schemes for contract labour, and so on.
We have already mentioned government attempts during the post-reform
period to decentralize bargaining in public sector units by tying
unit-level wage increases to productivity increases (rather than
passing them on as price increases), and by consistently announcing
its refusal to provide budgetary support to these wage increases. The
central trade unions are uniting to pre-empt a government attempt to
switch to a 10-year wage settlement in public sector units instead of
the present 5-year duration. Union leaders say the move will affect
the pay revision prospects of about 2 million workers in the public
sector. Private employers have been lobbying for some time to
increase the duration of contracts in public sector units so as to
prevent disruptions arising from frequent industrial disputes, the
costs of which they have to often bear. Unions, especially the All
India Trade Union Congress and the Indian National Trade Union
Congress, are strongly against such a move.
Even outside the public sector, pressures for decentralized bargaining
are emanating from both workers and employers. What happened in the
textile industry is now being repeated in the jute industry in and
around Calcutta. Due to the uneven development of textile firms in
Mumbai in the early 1980s, and due to the undemocratic nature of union
representation in the industry, both employers and unions in the more
profitable mills wanted to break away from the industry-wide agreement
in force and set up their own mill-level agreements (Bhattacherjee,
1988; 1989). Recently, employers in two jute mills defied the
industry-wide agreement between the Indian Jute Mills Association and
the many unions by offering a higher cost-of-living allowance to avert
mill-level strikes. The central trade unions are in a dilemma for the
first time in the jute industry: on the face of it, they oppose any
kind of bipartite settlement by insisting on an industry-wide
agreement at tripartite level. But by encouraging strikes at
individual mills, they are indirectly opening up routes for direct
negotiation between management and mill-level unions. The trend
towards decentralization is reflected in the rising number of unions
which have signed the industry-wide agreement: in 1972, there were
only four signatories, in 1979 there were 11, and in 1992 there were
16 (Sen, 1997, p. 104).
By decentralizing bargaining structures and expanding the scope and
duration of labour contracts, employers and the government are trying
to minimize the "monopoly effects" of union work rules
embedded in contract provisions that lead to considerable labour
market inflexibilities, especially at micro-level. The determinant of
public sector negotiations has been pay parity, and as a result there
are few incentive structures in this system. Centralized public
sector unions will have to come to terms with the microeconomic
requirements of productivity growth and increased competition. They
can learn from union responses to restructuring programmes in Europe.
(Endnote 25)
3.2.5 Industrial
conflict
Even though union density is very low by international standards,
India loses more days every year as a result of strikes and lockouts
than almost any other country (ILO, 1997/98, pp. 253-254). However,
the number of workers involved in strikes and lockouts is considerably
lower in India than in Brazil, Italy or Spain (pp. 251-252). This
raises the classic question of whether conflict reflects union power
or union weakness? It certainly indicates that the basic premise of
industrial pluralism, the regulation of conflict, has not been
achieved.
The answer to this question in India depends on whether workers resist
strikes or whether employers are on the offensive during lockouts.
Table 3 presents some time series conflict data. We note that during
the third and fourth phase, the number of lockouts rose whereas the
number of strikes decreased. The same applies to the number of
workdays lost and the number of workers involved. Until 1989
industrial conflict occurred mainly in the private sector in terms of
number of disputes, workdays and wages lost, and lost production,
although the actual number of workers involved in disputes was higher
in the public sector in the early 1980s. Since 1990, however,
industrial disputes in both sectors have increased significantly
(Venkataratnam, 1996).
Since the economic reforms of 1991, successive national governments
have had to deal with considerable industrial conflict in the public
sector, especially in banking, insurance, and transport. At regional
level, some state governments have had to contend with continuing
inter-union and inter-party rivalries, leading to the disruption of
public life. Of late, the government has followed a tough line on
striking public sector unions, as demonstrated in the dismissals and
criminal proceedings against air traffic controllers. There is an
imperative need for industrial relations reform in dispute settlement
as the average consumer and voter has increasingly come to be a key
actor and end-user of the industrial relations system. There are
significant differences between the main trade union federations on
the issues of secret strike ballot, prior notice to striking and the
period of notification, lay-off provisions, the role of voluntary
arbitration, multiple union situations, etc. The country as a whole
would gain if the union movement could arrive at a consensus and if
the recommendations of the Ramanujam Committee (statutory recognition
of "representative" trade unions and the creation of an
independent authority to arbitrate, mediate and enforce) were
implemented. The institution of arbitration, if effective, fair and
credible, will significantly improve the quality of industrial
pluralism.
3.2.6 Labour management
relations
Since the mid-1980s the practice of human resources management (HRM)
has significantly altered traditional union-management relations in
the advanced sectors of production, notably in multinationals and
other private firms. Since the economic reforms of 1991, some public
sector firms have also incorporated modern HRM practices into their
otherwise traditional labour-management relationship. Some of the
essential characteristics of these HRM practices are: attempts at
direct communication between managers and employees; individualized
and/or contingency pay systems; modular organization of production
through work teams with team leaders who often form part of the
management structure; carefully designed and fairly implemented
performance appraisal systems; and so on. While many would argue that
modern HRM practices undercut union effectiveness at enterprise level,
there is no clear evidence of this in India. Unions have a strong
presence in the firms where modern HRM practices are implemented
successfully, and it is only with cooperative union-management
behaviour that this has been possible. But this applies mainly to the
manufacturing sector.
In the skill-intensive service sectors such as information technology,
HRM practices continue to pose a challenge and possibly create
permanent barriers to union entry and organization. To the extent
that information technology redefines the nature of work in banking
and insurance, unions will have little success if they resist
modernization, given the entry of new, mainly foreign, players in
these sites. It is no coincidence that the most publicized
post-reform industrial conflict at national level has been in banking
and insurance.
If labour law reforms facilitate competitive pluralism and lead to
efficient collective bargaining in the private sector, and to
tripartism with responsibility and accountability in the public
sector, we can postulate that the effectiveness of unions would not
necessarily diminish if modern HRM practices were introduced in
enterprises.
3.2.7 Inter-state
variations
One critical reason why labour law reform has been continually debated
but ultimately shelved, is the lack of a consensus within the labour
movement and across different state governments. Since economic
liberalization, every state government has attempted to attract
national and international capital. This has involved significant
media costs, and many states have even hired international consultants
to draw up economic renewal agendas. A vital consideration in this
post-liberalization discourse has been the question of work ethic and
comparative union militancy.
Table 11 ranks the states in terms of the number and membership of
registered unions that submit returns according to the four phases of
unionism. Although the data are sketchy, some trends can be
discerned: (a) the more industrial states of Maharashtra and Tamil
Nadu have maintained their high rankings through the four phases; (b)
West Bengal ranks high during the first two phases, but we could not
find comparable data for the following two phases; and (c) Gujarat is
doing well during the fourth phase, no doubt reflecting the rise of
unions affiliated to the Bharatiya Janata Party.
One of the most important concerns of social scientists in India today
is the effect that economic liberalization will have on inter-state
variations in human development, social productivity and civil society
at large. States with a less organized labour movement, if controlled
by pro-capital state governments, may attempt to attract capital with
implicit promises of a union-free environment. This has clearly
happened to some extent and has often taken violent forms. Ruling
governments in other states with a long history of proletarian
politics are desperately attempting to change their signals. These
attempts are causing confusion within the union movement, both among
the leaders and the rank and file, and also leading to chasms between
political parties and their affiliated unions. In several instances,
temporary or issue-based alliances have been formed between unions
affiliated to opposition parties, especially with regard to
privatization of public sector services and utilities.
One example of a state government changing its signals after being in
power for over 20 years is the case of the CPI(M) in West Bengal. For
the last 20 years, the CPI(M) and its trade union wing, the CITU, has
been at the forefront of proletarian resistance to capitalist
production processes and management hierarchies that control the
labour process. The large-scale flight of industrial and commercial
capital from West Bengal, which has been occurring since at least the
mid-1960s, is attributed by many commentators to heightened industrial
conflict supported by a sympathetic state government. In the
meantime, the state's reputation declined, fuelled by a hostile local
press. But the fact that the industrial health of the state withered
during this time was there for everyone to see and experience.(Endnote 26)
Since the mid-1990s, the CPI (M) has attempted to attract national and
international capital at several well-publicized gatherings in
Calcutta, through government funded ministerial visits abroad, and
through promotional advertising. The state government has been sending
strong signals to the trade unions in the state to accept the
requirements of industrial regeneration. Unions and employees in
hospitals and nursing homes have been warned. As an important CPI(M)
minister put it recently: "In the name of trade unionism, we have
allowed many things. But enough is enough. We will take immediate
action if there's the slightest hint of agitation at a
hospital".(Endnote 27)
After nurturing (some would say pampering) the trade unions in the
state for so long, it is now very difficult to change attitudes,
behaviour, customs and institutionalized practices to facilitate
capitalist expansion, a process that was anathema to the CPI(M) for so
many years. With hindsight, one could argue that if the party had
thought out a strategy only a decade ago, the state could have reaped
considerable returns from an effective model of social democracy. In
the meantime, trade unions are now realizing that there is nothing
voluntary about the 'voluntary retirement schemes' being imposed on
workers in some well-known large firms.(Endnote 28)
Recently, tensions between the party and its affiliated union (the
CITU) came to the fore on two counts. At the Haldia Petrochemicals
Limited township the union is demanding that "sons of the
soil" be given permanent jobs in the Rs.51.7 billion project.
According to management such a recruitment policy would spell
financial disaster, and consequently, the state government has gone
against the wishes of its affiliated union.(Endnote 29) The second site where tensions
are currently running high is the transport sector in the city of
Calcutta, where due to environmental pressures the state government
wants to implement Euro I and Euro II emission standards as from 1999.
This would mean taking nearly 80 per cent of private buses and taxis
off the road. The transport workers' unions have threatened
indefinite strikes to cripple the public transport system in the city.
(Endnote 30)
Calcutta exemplifies the failure of state-controlled unionism where
"class consciousness" is dominant. In contrast, the
market-driven industrial relations system of Mumbai exemplifies a
decentralized regime where the important role played by individual
trade union leaders in the city's labour history has added to the
"job conscious" nature of industrial relations. Although
considerable growth has taken place in Mumbai, this regime has led to
almost uncontrollable and corrupt links between politics, the real
estate market and the organized labour movement. It is no wonder that
post-reform capital has invested in newer industrial locations, and
this logic is slowly but surely changing the industrial geography of
India (Shaw, 1999). It will thus become increasingly difficult, if
not impossible, to generalize about an Indian labour relations system.
3.2.8 Women workers and
unionization
The percentage of women members in trade unions that submit returns
rose from 7.3 per cent in 1951-52 to 10.3 per cent in 1985; in 1992 it
was 11.6 per cent (see table 2). Detailed information on the extent
of unionization among women workers is not available, although there
are rich case studies of specific sectors/industries where women
workers form a substantial section of the workforce (see the chapter
on tea plantations by Bhowmik in Davala, 1992).
There is considerable controversy on whether there has been an
increasing "feminization" of the workforce over the last
decade, especially since the liberalization process began. Deshpande
and Deshpande (1992, p. 1998) assessed the short-run impact of
liberalization on female employment and participation. They found
that: (a) in urban areas, both male and female participation rates
increased after liberalization; (b) gender-based wage differentials
widened among regular wage/salaried rural and urban workers; (c) women
workers were increasingly taking to self-employment and to the
informal sectors as their proportion in manufacturing declined even
though women's share in the urban workforce rose slightly.
Although in several countries globalization has led to feminization of
the manufacturing workforce, Banerjee (1997) argues that in India the
reverse has taken place: women's opportunities in the secondary
sectors have fallen drastically in all states. However, there has
been a slight increase in work opportunities for rural women in
agriculture and some gains were made in the tertiary sector.
According to Banerjee (1997, p. 433), it would be unrealistic to
expect a "mechanical reproduction of international trends in a
country the size of India". Women workers account for only 17 per
cent of the manufacturing workforce that in turn is only 13 per cent
of the total workforce. She goes on to suggest that even if the
entire export sector (commodities) were staffed by women, "it is
doubtful that this would result in a feminization of the Indian
manufacturing workforce as a whole".
Given that a substantial section of women workers in India today are
engaged as "homeworkers" in several industries (such as bangle
makers, cobblers, dye makers, flower workers, kite makers, lace
makers, leather workers, etc.), it is encouraging that the Indian
trade union movement, under the leadership of the Self-Employed
Women's Association (SEWA)(Endnote
31) has taken a lead in drafting an ILO convention on
homeworkers (Mukul, 1998).(Endnote
32) A bill was introduced in the upper house in 1988 that
attempted to equalize treatment of homeworkers with other wage earners
in terms of remuneration, health and safety, minimum wage and
maternity protection, with tripartite boards as the enforcement
mechanism. Although the bill was dropped, it did contribute to
initiating a national debate, according to Ela Bhatt, general
secretary of the SEWA (Mukul, 1998, p. 758).
The SEWA model, where poor working women in the informal sector are
organized so as to improve their wages and working conditions, and
also assisted with credit from banks and cooperatives, needs to be
replicated elsewhere in India with considerable urgency. This is
already happening in the Working Women's Forum in
Chennai and Annapurna in Mumbai. Established trade union
federations have to take a lead in fostering these organizational
models and cooperating with local NGOs where the situation warrants,
especially in states where gender equality is a serious problem (Seeta
Prabhu et al., 1996). The CITU has made considerable progress in
organizing women workers in the informal sector.
Trade unions should lobby central and state governments to improve
education for women and increase state intervention in favour of
women's employment. There is also considerable scope for increasing
the number of women in leadership roles within the established trade
union federations.
3.2.9 Changing public
perception of trade unions
The memories of nationalism and independence struggles sustained the
image of trade unions as the collective voice of the oppressed,
dispossessed and the exploited during the first two phases of
unionism. In the third phase, segmented and uneven economic growth
fractured union voices, and the public was able to distinguish between
them. The Mumbai textile strike of 1982-83 generated considerable
solidarity, not just within the organized labour movement, but among
the urban citizenry at large. At the same time, however, impatience
with the declining work ethic and a growing lack of accountability in
the public sector, especially in service and education, often reached
critical levels.
Since the liberalization process in 1991-92, the print and visual
media have clearly supported globalization. By and large, organized
labour, especially in the public sector, has not received a
sympathetic press; in fact, coverage of trade union matters has
declined considerably. At the same time though, considerable media
attention is given to the conditions of unorganized workers, child and
women workers, and to the attempts by non-governmental organizations
to improve the status of disadvantaged groups. Trade unions in India
today face the challenge of convincing the public that they can act on
behalf of all employees, unionized or not. This requires the
formation of strategic alliances with community bodies, social
movements, and other non-governmental organizations. Trade unions
will have to come to accept that the credibility of political parties
is at a very low level. There is considerable scope for the trade
union movement to capitalize on potential alliances, and a concrete
beginning can be made by first forging alliances among themselves.
However, this could entail a weakening of links with their political
parties.
Future role of trade unions in India:
Organizing the unorganized
The future role of the trade union movement is linked with a broader
concern for ensuring the social cohesion of working people in a large
and diverse country. In this final section, we examine union
strategies in the private corporate sector, in public sector
enterprises, and in the informal sector. It is imperative for the
trade union movement to concentrate on organizing the unorganized, so
as to create secure incomes and safe working conditions for those with
irregular and precarious jobs.
4.1 The private corporate
sector
On average, private enterprises employ around 30 per cent of all
formal sector workers in India; in manufacturing and trade, this
proportion is around 70 per cent, whereas in transport, electricity
and construction the figure is less than 5 per cent (Datta Chaudhuri,
1996).
In successful private companies enterprise-based trade unions (that
may or may not be politically affiliated) will have to accept that
their pay is partly (if not largely) determined by productivity.
Rather than blind resistance to this kind of pay structure, a
cooperative strategy may pay greater dividends in terms of gainsharing
at enterprise level. Unions will have to use their "collective
voice" effectively in collective bargaining when incentive
structures are proposed and negotiated. While the independent unions
will find this strategy quite natural, those which are affiliated to
the centralized federations may find it difficult. In either case,
the extent to which a union is willing to take a risk will partly
determine the composition of pay (performance-based "risk" pay
and "steady" pay).
While the majority of contracts in this sector are (and probably
always will be) negotiated at enterprise- or plant-level, unions in
some organizations, possibly in the multinationals, could concentrate
on attaining firm-wide agreements in the face of considerable
management opposition. Firm-wide agreements will strengthen union
power at the corporate-level, and to achieve this, unions may have to
trade off some plant-level gains. An example of this situation is
being played out at Bata India. Management recognizes the enterprise
unions in its various plants across the country, but the loosely
united All India Bata Employees Federation is not recognized. It
appears that management is willing to talk to the federation if it
agrees to restructuring plans at the plant in Faridabad. If the
federation agrees to these plans in exchange for management
recognition, this would clearly reduce union influence at the plant.
In the older industries in the private sector, where industry-wide
bargaining is the dominant structure and where inter-firm
differentiation has grown considerably since liberalization, unions
and employers are finding it difficult to reach industry-level
agreements. Unions will continue to face obstacles to industry-wide
solidarity in this sector.
What have been the effects of economic liberalization on the
connections between unions and political parties, and what has this
meant for the private corporate sector? To the extent that most of
the centralized trade unions continue to oppose the basic implications
of economic liberalization, there has been a surprising reconciliation
of unions affiliated to opposing political parties on a range of
issues at both regional and national level. There has been a gap
between the preoccupations of political parties and the
macro-objectives of trade unions since the reforms. This has created
a dilemma for most of the unions in this sector: while the loosening
of ties with the parent body inevitably leads to greater autonomy in
decentralized decision-making, it also means a lessening of
centralized lobbying power. Market forces will increasingly dominate
union strategies in this sector.
4.2 Public sector
enterprises
On average, the public sector employs around 70 per cent of all formal
sector workers in India; in transport, mining, construction,
electricity and services this proportion is high (>80 per cent),
but it is considerably lower in agriculture (40 per cent),
manufacturing (<40 per cent), and trade (<35 per cent) (Datta
Chaudhuri, 1996).
In non-viable public sector enterprises that are ready for closure,
most of which are in the East, the situation continues to be very
grim. Workers have not been paid for several months and the endless
talk of revival now sounds hollow. The closure of these firms seems
to be the only solution and unions can do no more than see that
lay-offs are implemented fairly and as generously as possible. In
several state-owned enterprises and organizations unions have accepted
that privatization is the only way of saving the unit, and that
informed negotiation is required.
As a result of increased competition from both domestic and
international producers, the output of public enterprises and services
has improved substantially. Nowhere is this more true than in the
state-run airlines. But unions in the public sector, especially those
in services such as medicine, education, the police and municipal
workers, can substantially increase their credibility by agreeing to
enforceable accountability procedures. This would mean internal
monitoring, which the unions are reluctant to accept.
Although the government has indicated a preference for
decentralization, the centralized bargaining structures have not yet
been dismantled. Unions could campaign for a restructured central
system that allows for greater local autonomy and minimizes
bureaucratic inflexibilities. For the public sector to deliver
long-run productivity improvements in the post-liberalization period,
unions will have to partly align their objectives with those of the
end-user - the average voter/consumer - who has become an important
voice in the labour relations system.
4.3 The informal
sector
In terms of union density, India fares rather badly compared to other
large developing countries. According to the ILO World Labour
Report 1997-98, union membership as a percentage of
non-agricultural labour dropped from 6.6 per cent in 1985 to 5.5 per
cent in 1995 (the corresponding figure in 1995 for Argentina was 23.4
per cent, Brazil 32.1 per cent and Mexico 31 per cent). Union
membership as a percentage of formal sector workers in India declined
from 26.5 per cent to 22.8 per cent between 1985 and 1995 (the
corresponding figures in 1995 were Argentina 65.6 per cent, Brazil 66
per cent, Mexico 72.9 per cent). If the figures are derived only from
registered unions that submit returns, it is possible that they may
somewhat underestimate union density in India. According to the above
source, less than 2 per cent of workers in the formal and informal
sectors in India are covered by collective bargaining agreements.
Clearly, a large proportion of workers (certainly those in the formal
sector) fall within the ambit of labour legislation, even though they
are not covered by a collective agreement. Nevertheless, it is
apparent that considerable organization of workers remains to be
undertaken in the Indian economy.
If one were to assume that the formal sector corresponds with the
unionized sector (in reality, the unionized sector is a subset of the
formal sector), then the following figures give an idea of the extent
to which unions in future can organize workers in the various
sectors. In total, less than 10 per cent of all workers are in the
formal sector. The proportion of workers in this sector by industry
groups is: mining and quarrying (56.9 per cent), manufacturing (19 per
cent), construction (17.5 per cent), trade (2.1 per cent), transport
(38.7 per cent), and services (38.7 per cent). Clearly, there is
enormous potential for organizing workers in construction,
manufacturing and trade. In addition, detailed surveys in several
industries have found that the existing unions do not sufficiently
represent the interests of casual and temporary workers (see the
studies in Davala, 1992). Finally, according to National Sample
Survey Organization data, there is a "high incidence of women's
involvement in unorganized sector activities, ranging anywhere between
20 to 25 per cent of total employment in urban areas and anywhere
between 30 to 40 per cent of total employment in rural areas - figures
which far outweigh women's recorded involvement in productive
activities from Census sources" (Mukhopadhyay, 1997, p. 485).
In sharp contrast to the formal sector, "the unorganized sector
has little by way of protective legislation or union
representation" (Anant and Sundaram, 1998, p. 833). In this site,
the "not so invisible" forces of demand and supply determine
wages and working conditions. There are no automatic cost-of-living
adjustments and substantial improvements are required in designing
need-based minimum wages for unorganized workers (Jhabvala, 1998) and
providing them with assured employment for a minimum number of days
(Unni, 1998). In this regard, the government's recent signal about
labour law reform consisting of "umbrella legislation for welfare
of unorganized sector workers" as part of the agenda should be
critically examined. The government proposes to relax contract labour
laws so as to generate more jobs, arguing that this would ensure
better overall security and welfare provisions for unorganized
workers. Unions, however, feel that any such move will only undermine
permanent jobs. In any case, there are strong economic reasons why
the wages and working conditions of informal sector workers should be
improved through welfare legislation. Such measures improve the
capabilities of the disadvantaged and vulnerable sections of working
people. In the absence of enhanced capabilities the economy suffers a
net loss.
It is clear that unions have a whole range of workers to organize in
the coming years, since the majority of labour market entrants will
probably work as self-employed or casual/temporary/ contract workers.
Visaria and Minhas (1991) estimate that nearly 80 million people will
join the labour force between 1990 and 2000. A whole range of
non-governmental organizations have successfully organized (not
necessarily unionized) several informal sector occupations and sites
in India during the last decade, but it seems that these interventions
are resented by the established trade union federations as an
intrusion into their terrain (often, it is claimed, with financial
backing from abroad). These fears are probably unwarranted, and
cooperation between trade unions and NGOs is required to level up
working conditions in these relatively neglected labour markets.
One way of organizing workers could be through union mergers and a
joint trade union front. However, the latter presupposes a certain
number of shared objectives among the large centralized trade union
federations, and this unity is not yet on the agenda. The All India
Trade Union Congress, the Hind Mazdoor Sabha, and the Indian National
Trade Union Congress have talked of mergers and unity, but the Centre
of Indian Trade Unions has taken a different approach; they have
proposed a confederation of central trade unions which will preserve
the individual identities (Muralidhar, 1994).The large unions have
considerable differences on the efficacy of a secret ballot system to
generate the legitimate bargaining agent. However, one good sign is
the increasing willingness of trade union federations to work together
in spite of the differences between their political parties on reform.
In many states acute differences are surfacing between political
parties and their affiliated unions and these issues are now being
openly debated.
It is well-known that the informal sector in India contributes
significantly to employment generation and to value added in
industry. It is also true that there are considerable links between
the formal and informal sectors and that there is a crucial regional
dimension to informal sector manufacturing (Shaw, 1990; 1994). The
attempt to unionize the unorganized in India has been difficult,
although some progress has been made in certain regions with
sympathetic state governments. But in other states, the situation of
informal sector workers remains grim, and will probably get worse
unless there is a concerted effort by trade unions and NGOs, hopefully
with the assistance of local and state governments, to level up the
labour market institutions of the informal sector. In these
endeavours, the organized labour movement should not view NGOs as
competitors.
To what extent will alliances between trade unions break the links
with their respective political parties? Or, will such alliances lead
to the emergence of national unions without explicit political
affiliation? It is too early to answer these questions but the
tensions between some political parties and their trade union
affiliates have come onto the regional and national stage since
economic liberalization began in the early 1990s. In the private
sector, these tensions emerged during the third phase of unionism and
resulted in the proliferation of independent unions. It may be
premature to suggest that independent unions, if they can be organized
at industry/regional level, will lead to far greater "collective
voice" effects and less "monopoly" effects than the
existing industrial relations system. With economic liberalization
and its effects on regional variations in economic activity, it seems
that battles over working conditions will increasingly be fought at
local and regional levels. Trade unions will have to forge deep links
with neighbourhoods and communities, urban movements, environmental
groups and regional NGOs to enhance their effective power.
Ultimately, it all depends on "public action", participation
in the process of social change. Public action refers not to what the
state does for the public, but to action taken by the public (Dreze
and Sen, 1989). The trade union movement could trigger this much
needed "public action" through broad-based alliances.
References
Ahluwalia, I.J.1991. Productivity and growth in Indian
manufacturing (New Delhi, Centre for Policy Research) (mimeo).
-. 1992. Redefining the role of the state: India at the
crossroads (New Delhi, Centre for Policy Research) (mimeo).
Anant, T.C.A.; Sundaram, K. 1998. " Wage policy in India: A
review", in The Indian Journal of Labour Economics,
Vol. 41, Oct.-Dec., pp. 815-834.
Bagchi, A.K. 1982. The political economy of
underdevelopment (Cambridge, Cambridge University Press).
Bain, G.S.; Elsheikh, F. 1976. Union growth and the
business cycle: An econometric analysis (Oxford,
Blackwell).
Banaji, J.; Hensman, R. 1990. Beyond multinationalism:
Management policy and bargaining relationships in
international companies (New Delhi, Sage).
-; -. 1995. "India: Multinationals and the resistance to
unionised labour", in International Union Rights, Vol. 2,
No.2, pp. 5-6.
Banerjee, N. 1997. "How real is the bogey of
feminization?", in The Indian Journal of Labour
Economics, Vol. 40, July-Sep., pp. 427-438.
Basu, K. 1995. Do India's labour laws hurt Indian laborers?
A theoretical investigation, Center for Analytical Economics,
Working Paper 95-12 (Ithaca, Cornell University).
Bhaduri, A. 1993. "Orthodox development theories and their
application to less developed countries", in Vaggi, G. (ed.):
From debt crisis to sustainable development: Changing
perspectives on north-south relationship (London, St.Martin's
Press).
-; Nayyar, D. 1996. An intelligent person's guide to
liberalization (New Delhi, Penguin India).
Bhagwati, J.; Srinivasan, T.N. 1975. Foreign trade regimes
and economic development (New York, Columbia University Press).
Bhattacherjee, D. 1987a. Union-type, labour market
structure, and bargaining outcomes in Indian
manufacturing. Unpublished Ph.D. thesis. (Urbana-Champaign,
University of Illinois).
-. 1987b. "Union-type effects on bargaining outcomes in
Indian manufacturing", in British Journal of Industrial
Relations, Vol. 27, (July), pp. 247-266.
-.1988. "Unions, state and capital in Western India:
Structural determinants of the 1982 Bombay textile strike", in
Southall, R. (ed.): Labour and unions in Africa and Asia:
Contemporary issues (London, Macmillan), pp.211-237.
-. 1989. "Evolution of unionism and labour market
structure: Case of Bombay textile mills, 1947-85", in Economic
and Political Weekly, Vol. 24, (May), M67-M76.
-. 1992. "Determinants of bargaining structure in India: An
exploratory exercise", in Economic and Political Weekly,
Vol. 27, (May), M71-M74.
-. 1996. "Economic liberalization, democracy and industrial
relations: India in a comparative perspective", in Indian
Journal of Labour Economics, Vol. 39, (Oct.-Dec.), pp. 1011-1022.
-. 1997. "Labour truths", in The Telegraph,
(Calcutta), 19 Sep .
-; Datta Chaudhuri, T. 1994a. "Modelling trade union growth
in India", in Indian Journal of Labour Economics,
Vol. 37, (Jan.-Mar.), pp. 67-72.
-; -. 1994b. "Unions, wages and labour markets in Indian
industry, 1960-86", in Journal of Development Studies,
Vol. 30, (Jan.), pp. 443-465.
Borjas, G. 1996. Labor economics (Singapore,
McGraw-Hill).
Breman, J. 1995. "Labour, get lost: A late-capitalist
manifesto", in Economic and Political Weekly,
Vol. 30, (16 Sep.), pp. 2294-2300.
Buchele, R.; Christiansen, J. 1992. "Industrial relations
and productivity growth: A comparative perspective", in
International Contributions to Labour Studies, Vol. 2,
pp. 77-97.
Chakrabarty, D. 1989. Rethinking working-class history
(Princeton, Princeton University Press).
Chakraborty, S.K. 1991. Management by values: Towards
cultural congruence (New Delhi, Oxford University Press).
Chatterjee, R. 1980. Unions, politics, and the state: A
study of Indian labour politics (New Delhi, South Asian
Publishers).
Chaudhuri, S. 1995. "Government and transnationals: New
economic policies since 1991", in Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 30, (6-13 May), pp. 999-1012.
Corbo, V.; Fisher, S. 1995. "Structural adjustment:
Stabilization and policy reform - Domestic and international
finance", in Behrman, J.; Srinivasan, T.N. (eds.): Handbook of
development economics, Vol.3 (Amsterdam, Elsevier.).
Costabile, L. 1996. "Institutions, social custom and
efficiency wage models: Alternative approaches", in Cambridge
Journal of Economics, Cambridge, Vol. 19, pp. 605-623.
D'Souza, E. 1998. "World employment: ILO perspective",
in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 33, (26
Sep.-2 Oct.), pp. 2537-2545.
Datta, R.C. 1998. "Public action, social security and
unorganised sector", in Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 33, (30 May-5 June), L2-L5.
Datta Chaudhuri, M. 1996. Labor markets as social
institutions in India. IRIS India Working Paper No.10 (College
Park, MD).
Datta Chaudhuri, T.; Bhattacherjee, D. 1994. "A structural
model of strikes and wages in Indian industry, 1960-86", in
Indian Journal of Industrial Relations, Vol. 30, (Oct.),
pp. 144-155.
Davala, S. (ed.). 1992. Employment and unionization in
Indian industry (New Delhi, FES).
-. 1992. "Chemical and pharmaceutical industry in
Maharashtra", in Davala, S. (ed.): op.cit., pp. 191-222.
-. 1996. "Independent trade unionism in West Bengal",
in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 31, (28
Dec.), L44-L49.
Desai, M. 1975. "India: Emerging contradictions of slow
capitalist development", in Blackburn, R. (ed.): Explosion in
a subcontinent (London, Penguin), pp. 11-51.
Deshpande, J.V. 1998. "College teachers' strike: An
assessment", in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 33,
(19 Sep.), pp. 2430-2432.
Deshpande, L.K. 1992. "Institutional interventions in the
labour market in Bombay's manufacturing sector", in Papola, T.S.;
Rodgers, G. (eds.): Labour institutions and economic development
in India. Research Series No. 97 (Geneva, International Institute
for Labour Studies).
Deshpande, S.; Deshpande, L.K. 1992. "New economic policy
and female employment", in Economic and Political Weekly,
Vol. 27, (Oct.), pp. 2248-2252.
-; -. 1996. "New economic policy and response of the labour
market in India", Paper presented to a seminar on
"Labour markets and
industrial relations in South Asia: Emerging issues and policy
options" (India International Centre, New Delhi, 18-20 Sep.)
-; -. 1998. "Impact of liberalisation on labour market in
India: What do facts from NSSO's 50th round show?", in
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 33, (30 May), L31-L39.
Doeringer,P.; Piore, M. 1971. Internal labor markets and
manpower analysis (Lexington, D.C. Heath).
Dreze, J.; Sen, A.K. 1989. Hunger and public action
(Oxford, Clarendon Press).
Edgren, G. 1990. "Employment adjustment and the
unions", in International Labour Review (Geneva,
ILO), Vol.129, No. 5, pp. 629-648.
Fallon. P.R.; Lucas, R.E.B. 1991. "The impact of changes in
job security regulations in India and Zimbabwe", in The World
Bank Economic Review, Vol. 5, (Sep.), pp. 395-413.
FES-IIRA. 1996. Social clause in trade: Trade unions'
perspective (New Delhi, FES).
Fonseca, A.J. 1964. Wage determination and organized labour
in India (Bombay, Oxford University Press).
Freeman, R. 1992. "Labor market institutions and policies:
Help or hindrance to economic development?", Proceedings of
the World Bank Conference on Development Economics,
pp.117-144.
-; Medoff, J. 1984. What do unions do? (New York,
Basic Books).
Ghose, A.K. 1992. "Economic restructuring, employment and
safety nets: A note", in Social dimensions of structural
adjustment in India (New Delhi, ILO-ARTEP), pp. 94-102.
Guptan, S.U. 1992. "Engineering industry in Andhra
Pradesh", in Davala, S. 1992. op.cit., pp. 113-144.
Hensman, R. 1996. "Minimum labour standards and trade
agreements: An overview of the debate", in Economic and
Political Weekly, Vol. 31, (20-27 Apr.), pp. 1030-1034.
Hiro, D. 1976. Inside India Today (New York, Monthly
Review Press).
Holmstrom, M. 1984. Industry and inequality: The social
anthropology of Indian labour (Cambridge,
Cambridge University Press).
Horton, S.; Kanbur, R.; Mazumdar, D. 1991. Labor markets in
an era of adjustment. Policy, Research, and External
Affairs Working Paper No. 694 (Washington, D.C., The World Bank).
Illustrated Weekly of
India. 1985. "State of the unions", (10-16 Feb.),
pp. 18-23.
ILO. 1996-97. World employment - National policies in a
global context (Geneva, ILO).
-. 1997-98. World Labour Report, Industrial relations,
democracy and social stability (Geneva, ILO).
Jackson, D.A.S. 1972. "Wage policy and industrial relations
in India", in Economic Journal, Vol. 82, (Mar.),
pp. 183-194.
Jaitly, J. 1997. "Organising the unorganised in Kerala:
Case studies of Aruvacode and Kodungallur", in Economic and
Political Weekly, Vol. 32, (12 July), pp. 1729-1736.
Jhabvala, R. 1995. "Invisible workers reach international
heights", in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 30, (9
Dec.), pp. 3133-3136.
-. 1998. "Minimum wages based on workers' needs", in
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 33, (7-13 Mar.),
pp. 500-502.
Johri, C.K. 1967. Unionism in a developing economy: A study
of the interaction between trade unionism and government policy in
India, 1950-65 (Bombay, Asia Publishing House).
Jose, A.V. 1992. "Earnings, employment and productivity
trends in organised industries in India", in
Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Vol. 35,
(Jul.-Sep.).
Joseph, K.P. 1997. "Piped music and telephone attendants:
Report of Fifth Pay Commission", in Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 32, (22 Mar.), pp. 563-565.
-. 1999. "Government pay and perks: Growing chaos", in
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 34, (15 May),
p. 1167-1170.
Joshi, V.; Little, I.M.D. 1994. India: Macroeconomics and
political economy, 1964-1991 (Washington, D.C., The World Bank).
-; -. 1996. India's economic reforms 1991-2001 (New
Delhi, Oxford University Press).
Karnik, V.B. 1966. Indian trade unions: A survey
(Bombay, Manaktalas).
Katz, H. 1993. "Decentralization of collective bargaining:
A literature review and comparative analysis", in Industrial
and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 47, (Oct.), pp. 3-22.
Kennedy, V.D. 1966. Unions, employers and government
(Bombay, Manaktalas).
Kingdon, G.G. 1997. "Labour force participation, returns to
education and sex discrimination in India", in Indian Journal
of Labour Economics, Vol. 40, (Jul.-Sep.), pp. 507-526.
Madan, B.K. 1977. The real wages of industrial labour in
India (New Delhi, Management Development Institute).
Mathur, A.N. 1992. Employment security and industrial
restructuring in India: Separating facts from folklore - The exit
policy controversy (Calcutta, Indian Institute of Management).
-. 1993. "The experience of consultation during structural
adjustment in India (1990-92)", in International Labour
Review (Geneva, ILO), Vol. 132, No. 3, pp. 331-345.
Mazumdar, D. 1997. "Labour markets, trade patterns and
workers' living standards", in Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 32,(1-14 Mar.), pp. 463-474.
Milgrom, P.; Roberts, J. 1992. Economics, organization and
management (New Jersey, Prentice-Hall).
Mitra, A. 1977. Terms of trade and class relations
(London, Frank Cass).
Morris, M.D. 1955. "Labor discipline, trade unions, and the
state in India", in Journal of Political Economy,
Vol. 33, (July), pp. 293-308.
-. 1965. Emergence of an industrial labor force in
India (Berkeley, University of California Press).
Mukhopadhyay, S. 1997. "Locating women within informal
sector hierarchies", in Indian Journal of Labour
Economics, Vol. 40, (July-Sep.), pp. 483-492.
Mukul, 1998. "Homeworkers: High hopes and
hard realities", in Economic and Political Weekly,
Vol. 33, (4-10 Apr.), pp. 758-762.
Mundle, S. 1992. "The employment effects of stabilisation
and related policy changes, 1992-1994", in Social dimensions
of structural adjustment in India (New Delhi, ILO-ARTEP),
pp. 25-40.
Muralidhar, S. 1993. "Slipping through the holes in the
safety net", in Economic Times, (Calcutta), 26
Dec., p. 7.
-. 1994. " In tune with changing reality", in
Economic Times, (Calcutta), 13 Feb., p. 9. Myers,
C.M. 1958. Labor problems in the industrialization of India
(Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press).
Nagaraj, R. 1994. "Employment and wages in manufacturing
industries: Trends, hypothesis and evidence", in Economic and
Political Weekly, Vol. 29, (Jan.), pp. 177-186.
-. 1997. "What has happened since 1991? Assessment of
India's economic reform", in Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 32, (8-14 Nov.), pp. 2869-2879.
Nambiar, R.G.; Mungekar, B.L.; Tadas, G.A. 1999. "Is import
liberalization hurting domestic industry and employment?", in
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 34, (13-19 Feb.),
pp. 417-424.
Nayyar, D. 1981. "Industrial development in India: Growth
or stagnation?", in Bagchi, A.K.; Banerjee, N. (eds.): Change
and choice in Indian industry (Calcutta, K.P. Bagchi),
pp. 91-118.
Nelson, J.M. 1991. " Organized labor, politics and labor
market flexibility in developing countries", in World Bank
Research Observer, (Washington, D.C.), Vol. 6, pp. 37-56.
Noronha, E. 1996. "Liberalisation and industrial
relations", in Economic and Political Weekly,
Vol. 31, (24 Feb.), L14-L20.
Olson, M. 1971. The logic of collective action
(Cambridge, Harvard University Press).
Papola, T.S. 1994. "Employment growth and social protection
of labour in India", in Indian Journal of Industrial
Relations, Vol. 30, (Oct.), pp. 117-143.
Patankar, B. 1981. "Textile workers and Datta Samant",
in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 16, (Dec.),
pp. 1981-1982.
Patil, B.R. 1982. "Coalition and convertive
bargaining", in Indian Journal of Industrial Relations,
Vol. 18, (Oct.), pp. 241-262.
Patnaik, P.; Rao, S.K. 1977. "1975-76: Beginning of the end
of stagnation?" in Social Scientist, Vol. 5, (Jan.),
pp. 120-138.
Pendse, S. 1981. "The Datta Samant phenomenon", in
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 16, (Apr.), pp.
695-797 and 745-749.
Punekar, S.A. 1966. "Aspects of state intervention in
industrial relations in India", in Ross, A.M. (ed.):
Industrial relations and economic development
(London, Macmillan).
Raj, K.N. 1976. "Growth and stagnation in India's
industrial development", in Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 11, (Feb.), pp. 223-236.
Ramaswamy, E.A. 1973. "Politics and organized labour in
India", in Asian Survey, Vol. 13, No. 10, pp. 914-928.
-. 1984. Power and justice (New Delhi, Oxford
University Press)
-. 1988. Worker consciousness and trade union response
(New Delhi, Oxford University Press).
Ramaswamy, K.V. 1999. "The search for flexibility in Indian
manufacturing: New evidence on outsourcing activities", in
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 34, (6-12 Feb.),
pp. 363-368.
Rameshan, P. 1998. "Employment reduction under reforms and
the productivity of sick PSEs: A learning curve analysis", in
Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Vol. 41, (Jan.-Mar.),
pp. 105-118.
Rudolph, L.I.; Rudolph, S.H. 1987. In pursuit of
Lakshmi (Bombay, Orient Longmans). Seeta Prabhu, K.;
Sarkar, P.C.; Radha, A. 1996. "Gender-related development index
for Indian states: Methodological issues", in Economic and
Political Weekly, Vol. 31, (26 Oct.), WS72-WS79.
Sen, A. 1996. "Economic reforms, employment and poverty:
Trends and options", in Economic and Political Weekly,
Vol. 31, (Sep.), pp. 2459-2478.
Sen, R. 1992. "Jute industry", in Davala, S. 1992,
op.cit., pp. 41-62.
-. 1992. "Coal industry", in Davala, S. 1992,
op.cit., pp. 63-84.
-. 1997. "Changing employment and industrial relations in
the jute industry", in Venkataratnam, C.S.; Verma, A. (eds.):
Challenge of choice: Industrial relations in Indian industry
(New Delhi, Allied), pp. 65-104.
Sen, S.K. 1977. Working class of India: History and
movement, 1830-1970 (Calcutta, K.P. Bagchi).
Sengupta, A.K. 1992. Trends in industrial conflict in India
(1961-87) and government policy. Working Paper Series No. 174/92
(Calcutta, Indian Institute of Management).
Shaw, A. 1990. "Linkages of large scale, small scale and
informal sector industries: A study of Thana-Belapur", in
Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 25, (17 Feb.), M17-M22.
-. 1994. "The informal sector in Indian manufacturing
activities: A regional study", in Indian Journal of Labour
Economics, Vol. 37, (July-Sep.), pp. 335-350.
-. 1999. "Emerging patterns of urban growth in India",
in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 34, (17-24 Apr.),
pp. 969-978.
Subramaniam, D. 1997."Bangalore public sector strike,
1980-81: A critical appraisal", in Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 32, (12 Apr.), pp. 767-778.
Tulpule, B.; Datta, R.C. 1988. "Real wages in Indian
industry", in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 23,
(Oct.), pp. 2275-2277.
-. 1989. "Real wages and productivity in industry: A
disaggregated analysis", in Economic and Political
Weekly, Vol. 24, (Aug.), M94-M102.
Turnbull, P.J. 1991."Trade unions and productivity: Opening
the Harvard 'black boxes' ", in Journal of Labor
Research, Vol. 12, No. 2, pp. 135-149.
Unni, J. 1998. "Wages and employment in the unorganised
sector: Issues in wage policy", in Indian Journal of Labour
Economics, Vol. 41, (Oct.-Dec.), pp. 875-892.
Vaidyanathan, A. 1977. "Constraints on growth and policy
options", in Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. 12,
(Sep.), pp. 2105-2109.
Van Wersch, H. 1992. Bombay Textile Strike 1982-83
(New Delhi, Oxford University Press).
Venkataratnam, C.S. 1996. "Industrial relations in
India", Paper presented to a seminar on "Labour Market and
Industrial Relations in South Asia: Emerging Issues and Policy
Options" (New Delhi, India International
Centre, 18-20 Sep.).
-. 1997. "Economic liberalization and the transformation of
industrial relations policies in India", in Venkataratnam, C.S.;
Verma, A. (eds.): Challenge of Choice: Industrial Relations in
Indian Industry (New Delhi, Allied), pp. 12-64.
-; Verma, A. (eds.) 1997. Challenge of
choice: Industrial relations in Indian industry (New Delhi,
Allied).
Visaria, P.; Minhas, B.S. 1991. "Evolving an employment
policy for the 1990s: What do the data tell us?", in Economic
and Political Weekly, Vol. 26, (Apr.), pp. 969-979.
Weiner, M. 1962. The politics of scarcity (Chicago,
University of Chicago Press).
Williamson, O. 1985. The economic institutions of
capitalism: Firms, markets, and policy control (New York, New
York University Press).
World Bank. 1995. World Development Report, Workers in an
integrating world (Washington, D.C., World Bank).
Zeitlin, J. 1987. "From labour history to the history of
industrial relations", in Economic History Review,
Vol. 40, No. 2, pp. 159-184.
Appendix: Tables
Table 1. Employment in the organized sector (in 000,000s) |
Four phases of unionization |
Year (end of March) |
Employment |
|
|
Public sector |
Private sector |
Total |
The first phase (1950 to
mid-1960s) |
1956 |
52.34 |
… |
… |
1961 |
70.5 |
50.40 |
120.9 |
1962 |
74.17 |
51.60 |
125.77 |
1963 |
79.53 |
54.50 |
134.03 |
1964 |
84.54 |
57.80 |
142.34 |
1965 |
89.57 |
60.40 |
149.97 |
|
(Data above are not comparable with those which follow) |
The second phase (mid-1960s to 1979) |
1966 |
93.79 |
68.13 |
161.92 |
1967 |
96.34 |
66.84 |
163.18 |
1968 |
98.02 |
65.25 |
163.27 |
1969 |
100.95 |
65.28 |
166.23 |
1970 |
103.74 |
66.85 |
170.59 |
1971 |
107.31 |
67.42 |
174.73 |
1972 |
112.09 |
67.69 |
179.78 |
1973 |
119.71 |
68.49 |
188.2 |
1974 |
124.80 |
67.94 |
192.74 |
1975 |
128.83 |
68.08 |
196.91 |
1976 |
133.22 |
68.44 |
201.66 |
1977 |
137.66 |
68.67 |
206.33 |
1978 |
142.00 |
70.43 |
212.43 |
1979 |
146.76 |
72.08 |
218.84 |
The third phase (1980 to 1991) |
1980 |
150.79 |
72.27 |
223.06 |
1981 |
154.84 |
73.95 |
228.79 |
1982 |
159.46 |
75.47 |
234.93 |
1983 |
164.55 |
75.52 |
240.07 |
1984 |
168.69 |
73.45 |
242.14 |
1985 |
172.69 |
73.09 |
245.78 |
1986 |
176.83 |
73.73 |
250.56 |
1987 |
180.25 |
73.64 |
253.89 |
1988 |
183.20 |
73.92 |
257.12 |
1989 |
184.44 |
74.53 |
258.97 |
1990 |
187.72 |
75.82 |
263.54 |
1991 |
190.58 |
76.75 |
267.33 |
The fourth phase (1992 to 2000) |
1992 |
192.10 |
78.46 |
270.56 |
1993 |
193.26 |
78.51 |
271.77 |
1994 |
194.45 |
79.30 |
273.75 |
1995
(June) |
194.11 |
80.65 |
274.76 |
Source: (a) For 1956-1969, Basic Statistics
Relating to the Indian Economy, Vol. 1: All India, Centre for Monitoring
Indian Economy (CMIE), October 1980; and (b) For 1970-1994, India's Social
Sectors, CMIE, February 1996. Note: Organized sector covers all the
enterprises in the public sector and only the non-agricultural establishments
in the private sector employing 25 or more workers from 1961 to 1965 and 10 or
more workers from 1966 onwards. |
Table 2. Number of registered unions and membership of
unions submitting returns |
Four phases of unionization |
Year |
No. of registered trade unions |
No. of unions submitting returns |
Percentage of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions submitting returns (in thousands) |
Average membership per union submitting
returns |
|
|
|
|
|
Men |
Women |
Total |
|
The first phase
(1950 to mid-1960s) |
1949-50 |
3522 |
1919 |
54.5 |
1689 |
120 |
1809 |
949 |
1950-51 |
3766 |
2002 |
53.2 |
1649 |
106 |
1757 |
577 |
1951-52 |
4623 |
2556 |
55.3 |
1847 |
136 |
1996 |
781 |
1952-53 |
4934 |
2718 |
55.1 |
1936 |
157 |
2099 |
772 |
1953-54 |
6029 |
3295 |
54.7 |
1925 |
176 |
2113 |
641 |
1954-55 |
6658 |
3545 |
53.2 |
1940 |
229 |
2170 |
612 |
1955-56 |
8095 |
4007 |
49.5 |
2034 |
240 |
2275 |
568 |
1956-57 |
8554 |
4399 |
51.4 |
2097 |
280 |
2377 |
540 |
1957-58 |
10045 |
5520 |
55.0 |
2682 |
332 |
3015 |
546 |
1958-59 |
10228 |
6040 |
59.1 |
3255 |
392 |
3647 |
604 |
1959-60 |
10811 |
6588 |
60.9 |
3532 |
391 |
3923 |
596 |
1960-61 |
11312 |
6813 |
60.2 |
3618 |
395 |
4013 |
589 |
1961-62 |
11614 |
7087 |
61.0 |
3607 |
370 |
3977 |
561 |
1962-63 |
11827 |
7251 |
61.3 |
3335 |
347 |
3682 |
508 |
1963-64 |
11984 |
7250 |
60.5 |
3628 |
349 |
3977 |
548 |
1964-65 |
13023 |
7543 |
57.9 |
4113 |
353 |
4446 |
594 |
1965 |
13248 |
6932 |
52.3 |
3565 |
223 |
3788 |
546 |
The second phase
(mid-1960s to
1979) |
1966 |
14686 |
7244 |
49.3 |
4078 |
314 |
4392 |
606 |
1967 |
15314 |
7523 |
49.1 |
4197 |
329 |
4525 |
602 |
1968 |
16716 |
8851 |
52.9 |
4700 |
421 |
5121 |
579 |
1969 |
18837 |
8423 |
44.7 |
4546 |
355 |
4900 |
582 |
1970 |
20879 |
8537 |
40.9 |
4699 |
421 |
5120 |
600 |
1971 |
22484 |
9029 |
40.2 |
5083 |
387 |
5470 |
606 |
1972 |
24436 |
9074 |
37.1 |
4889 |
451 |
5340 |
589 |
1973 |
26788 |
9853 |
36.8 |
6103 |
477 |
6580 |
668 |
1974 |
28648 |
9800 |
34.2 |
5715 |
475 |
6190 |
632 |
1975 |
29438 |
10324 |
35.1 |
6063 |
488 |
6550 |
634 |
1976 |
29350 |
9778 |
33.3 |
6090 |
422 |
6512 |
666 |
1977 |
30810 |
9003 |
29.2 |
5548 |
486 |
6034 |
670 |
1978 |
32361 |
8727 |
27.0 |
5771 |
433 |
6203 |
711 |
1979 |
34430 |
10021 |
29.1 |
6915 |
559 |
7474 |
746 |
The third phase
(1980 to 1991) |
1980 |
36507 |
4432 |
12.1 |
3509 |
218 |
3727 |
841 |
1981 |
37539 |
6682 |
17.8 |
5012 |
385 |
5397 |
808 |
1982 |
38313 |
5044 |
13.2 |
2822 |
177 |
2999 |
595 |
1983 |
38935 |
6844 |
17.6 |
5011 |
406 |
5417 |
792 |
1984 |
42609 |
6451 |
15.1 |
4707 |
443 |
5150 |
798 |
1985 |
45067 |
7815 |
17.3 |
5831 |
602 |
6433 |
823 |
1986 |
45830 |
11365 |
24.8 |
7368 |
819 |
8187 |
720 |
1987 |
49329 |
11063 |
22.4 |
7211 |
748 |
7959 |
719 |
1988 |
50048 |
8730 |
17.4 |
6334 |
739 |
7073 |
810 |
1989 |
52210 |
9758 |
18.7 |
8207 |
1088 |
9295 |
953 |
1990 |
52016 |
8828 |
16.97 |
6181 |
838 |
7019 |
795 |
1991 |
53535 |
8418 |
15.7 |
5507 |
594 |
6100 |
725 |
The fourth phase
(1992 to 2000) |
1992 |
55680 |
9165 |
16.5 |
5148 |
598 |
5746 |
627 |
1993 |
55784 |
6806 |
12.2 |
-- |
-- |
3134 |
460 |
Source: Indian Labour Yearbook, Labour Bureau, various years.
|
Table 3.
Industrial conflict (1950-1997)
|
Four phases of
unionization |
Year |
Number of disputes |
No. of workers involved
in disputes (000's) |
No. of work days lost
in disputes (000's) |
|
|
Strikes |
Lock-outs |
Total |
Strikes |
Lock-outs |
Total |
Strikes |
Lock-outs |
Total |
The first phase
(1950 to mid-1960s) |
1950 |
-- |
-- |
814 |
-- |
-- |
720 |
-- |
-- |
12807 |
1951 |
-- |
-- |
1071 |
-- |
-- |
691 |
-- |
-- |
3819 |
1952 |
-- |
-- |
963 |
-- |
-- |
809 |
-- |
-- |
3337 |
1953 |
-- |
-- |
772 |
-- |
-- |
467 |
-- |
-- |
3383 |
1954 |
-- |
-- |
840 |
-- |
-- |
477 |
-- |
-- |
3373 |
1955 |
-- |
-- |
1166 |
-- |
-- |
528 |
-- |
-- |
5698 |
1956 |
-- |
-- |
1203 |
-- |
-- |
715 |
-- |
-- |
6992 |
1957 |
-- |
-- |
1630 |
-- |
-- |
889 |
-- |
-- |
6429 |
1958 |
-- |
-- |
1524 |
-- |
-- |
929 |
-- |
-- |
7798 |
1959 |
-- |
-- |
1531 |
-- |
-- |
694 |
-- |
-- |
5633 |
1960 |
-- |
-- |
1583 |
-- |
-- |
986 |
-- |
-- |
6537 |
1961 |
1240 |
117 |
1357 |
432 |
80 |
512 |
2969 |
1950 |
4919 |
1962 |
1396 |
95 |
1491 |
575 |
130 |
705 |
5059 |
1062 |
6121 |
1963 |
1364 |
107 |
1471 |
491 |
72 |
563 |
2229 |
1040 |
3269 |
1964 |
1981 |
170 |
2151 |
876 |
127 |
1003 |
5724 |
2001 |
7725 |
1965 |
1697 |
138 |
1835 |
889 |
102 |
991 |
4617 |
1853 |
6470 |
The second
phase (mid-1960s to 1979) |
1966 |
2353 |
203 |
2556 |
1262 |
148 |
1410 |
10377 |
3469 |
13846 |
1967 |
2433 |
382 |
2815 |
1340 |
151 |
1491 |
10565 |
6583 |
17148 |
1968 |
2451 |
325 |
2776 |
1465 |
204 |
1669 |
11078 |
6166 |
17244 |
1969 |
2344 |
283 |
2627 |
1687 |
140 |
1827 |
15477 |
3571 |
19048 |
1970 |
2598 |
291 |
2889 |
1552 |
276 |
1828 |
14749 |
5814 |
20563 |
1971 |
2478 |
274 |
2752 |
1476 |
139 |
1615 |
11803 |
4743 |
16546 |
1972 |
2857 |
386 |
3243 |
1475 |
262 |
1737 |
13748 |
6796 |
20544 |
1973 |
2958 |
421 |
3370 |
2358 |
187 |
2546 |
13862 |
6764 |
20626 |
1974 |
2501 |
428 |
2929 |
2710 |
145 |
2855 |
33643 |
6619 |
40262 |
1975 |
1644 |
299 |
1943 |
1033 |
111 |
1144 |
16706 |
5195 |
21901 |
1976 |
1241 |
218 |
1459 |
550 |
186 |
737 |
2799 |
9947 |
12746 |
1977 |
2691 |
426 |
3117 |
1912 |
281 |
2193 |
13410 |
11910 |
25320 |
1978 |
2762 |
425 |
3187 |
1690 |
226 |
1916 |
15423 |
12917 |
28340 |
1979 |
2709 |
339 |
3048 |
2714 |
159 |
2873 |
35804 |
8050 |
43854 |
The third phase
(1980 to 1991) |
1980 |
2501 |
355 |
2856 |
1661 |
239 |
1900 |
12018 |
9907 |
21925 |
1981 |
2245 |
344 |
2589 |
1261 |
327 |
1588 |
21208 |
15375 |
36583 |
1982 |
2029 |
454 |
2483 |
-- |
-- |
1469 |
-- |
-- |
74615 |
1983 |
1993 |
495 |
2488 |
-- |
-- |
1461 |
-- |
-- |
46858 |
1984 |
1689 |
405 |
2094 |
-- |
-- |
1949 |
-- |
-- |
56025 |
1985 |
1355 |
400 |
1755 |
878 |
201 |
1079 |
11487 |
17753 |
29240 |
1986 |
1458 |
434 |
1892 |
1444 |
200 |
1644 |
18824 |
13925 |
32749 |
1987 |
1348 |
451 |
1799 |
1495 |
275 |
1770 |
14026 |
21332 |
35358 |
1988 |
1304 |
441 |
1745 |
937 |
254 |
1191 |
12530 |
21417 |
33947 |
1989 |
1397 |
389 |
1786 |
1158 |
206 |
1364 |
10695 |
21968 |
32663 |
1990 |
1459 |
366 |
1825 |
1162 |
146 |
1308 |
10640 |
13446 |
24086 |
1991 |
1278 |
532 |
1810 |
872 |
470 |
1342 |
12428 |
14000 |
26428 |
The fourth phase (1992 to 2000) |
1992 |
1011 |
703 |
1714 |
767 |
485 |
1252 |
15132 |
16127 |
31259 |
1993 |
914 |
479 |
1393 |
672 |
282 |
954 |
5615 |
14686 |
20301 |
1994 |
808 |
393 |
1201 |
626 |
220 |
846 |
6651 |
14332 |
20983 |
1995 |
732 |
334 |
1066 |
683 |
307 |
990 |
5720 |
10570 |
16290 |
1996 |
-- |
-- |
1166 |
-- |
-- |
939 |
-- |
-- |
20285 |
1997 |
-- |
-- |
1305 |
-- |
-- |
981 |
-- |
-- |
17033 |
Source: Various issues of: Indian Labour Yearbook, Labour
Bureau; Indian Labour Statistics, Labour Bureau; Indian
Labour Journal, Labour Bureau. |
Table 4.
Economic indicators
|
Four phases of unionization
|
Plans |
Annual average growth rates |
|
|
GDP
|
Employment |
The first phase
(1950 to mid-1960s) |
1951-56
(First Five-Year Plan) |
3.6 |
0.39 |
|
1956-61
(Second Five-Year Plan) |
4.2 |
0.85 |
|
1961-66
(Third Five-Year Plan) |
2.8 |
2.03 |
The second phase
(mid-1960s to 1979) |
1967-69
(Annual Plans) |
3.9 |
2.21 |
|
1969-74
(Fourth Five-Year Plan) |
3.3 |
1.99 |
|
1974-79
(Fifth Five-Year Plan) |
4.8 |
1.84 |
The third phase
(1980-1991) |
1980-85
(Sixth Five-Year Plan) |
5.7 |
1.73 |
|
1985-90
(Seventh Five-Year Plan) |
5.8 |
1.89 |
|
1990-92
(Annual Plans) |
3.4 |
1.5 |
The fourth phase
(1992-2000) |
1992-97
(Eighth Five-Year Plan) |
NA |
NA |
|
1997-2002
(Ninth Five-Year Plan) |
NA |
NA |
Source: Five-Year Plan and Intervening Annual Plan Documents as in Papola (1994).
|
Table 5.
Employment elasticities in major sectors
|
Sector |
1972-73 to
1977-78 |
1977-78 to
1983 |
1983 to
1987-88 |
Agriculture |
0.66 |
0.49 |
0.36 |
Mining |
0.95 |
0.67 |
0.85 |
Manufacturing |
0.55 |
0.42 |
0.26 |
Construction |
0.35 |
1.00 |
1.00 |
Electricity, gas and water supply |
1.00 |
0.74 |
0.48 |
Transport, storage and communications |
0.76 |
0.92 |
0.35 |
Services |
0.80 |
0.99 |
0.42 |
All sectors |
0.61 |
0.55 |
0.38 |
Source: Papola (1994). |
Table 6. Sectoral distribution of employment in the formal
economy (in 000,000s)
|
Year (ending in March ) |
Agriculture and allied |
Mining and quarrying |
Manufacturing |
Power, gas and water supply |
Construction |
Services@ |
|
Public Sector |
Private Sector |
Total |
Public Sector |
Private Sector |
Total |
Public Sector |
Private Sector |
Total |
Public Sector |
Private Sector |
Total |
Public Sector |
Private Sector |
Total |
Public Sector |
Private Sector |
Total |
1961* |
1.80 |
6.70 |
8.50 |
1.29 |
5.50 |
6.79 |
3.69 |
30.20 |
33.89 |
2.24 |
0.40 |
2.64 |
6.03 |
2.40 |
8.43 |
55.45 |
5.20 |
60.65 |
1975* |
3.34 |
8.18 |
11.52 |
6.94 |
1.23 |
8.17 |
10.19 |
41.11 |
51.30 |
5.08 |
0.39 |
5.47 |
9.56 |
1.27 |
10.83 |
93.72 |
15.89 |
109.61 |
1976 |
3.59 |
8.27 |
11.86 |
7.19 |
1.32 |
8.51 |
11.13 |
41.58 |
52.71 |
5.36 |
0.35 |
5.71 |
9.92 |
0.94 |
10.86 |
93.52 |
15.99 |
109.51 |
1977 |
3.66 |
8.38 |
12.04 |
7.57 |
1.30 |
8.87 |
12.26 |
41.65 |
53.91 |
5.63 |
0.35 |
5.98 |
10.09 |
0.83 |
10.92 |
98.45 |
16.18 |
114.63 |
1978 |
3.87 |
8.53 |
12.40 |
7.58 |
1.27 |
8.85 |
13.55 |
43.21 |
56.76 |
5.99 |
0.34 |
6.33 |
9.98 |
0.83 |
10.81 |
101.03 |
16.25 |
117.28 |
1979 |
4.08 |
8.41 |
12.49 |
7.71 |
1.24 |
8.95 |
14.16 |
44.33 |
58.49 |
6.34 |
0.34 |
6.68 |
10.32 |
0.83 |
11.15 |
104.14 |
16.93 |
121.07 |
1980 |
4.31 |
8.60 |
12.91 |
7.97 |
1.25 |
9.22 |
14.46 |
44.17 |
58.63 |
6.61 |
0.34 |
6.95 |
10.68 |
0.73 |
11.41 |
106.77 |
17.18 |
123.95 |
1981 |
4.63 |
8.58 |
13.21 |
8.18 |
1.30 |
9.48 |
15.02 |
45.45 |
60.47 |
6.83 |
0.35 |
7.18 |
10.89 |
0.72 |
11.61 |
109.29 |
17.55 |
126.84 |
1983 |
4.76 |
8.47 |
13.23 |
8.84 |
1.20 |
10.04 |
16.34 |
45.56 |
61.90 |
7.21 |
0.37 |
7.58 |
11.20 |
0.68 |
11.88 |
116.20 |
18.24 |
134.44 |
1984 |
4.89 |
8.19 |
13.08 |
9.27 |
1.13 |
10.40 |
17.17 |
44.73 |
61.91 |
7.33 |
0.39 |
7.72 |
11.20 |
0.66 |
11.86 |
118.81 |
18.41 |
137.22 |
1985 |
4.98 |
8.22 |
13.20 |
9.74 |
1.13 |
10.87 |
17.60 |
44.23 |
61.83 |
7.59 |
0.39 |
7.98 |
11.46 |
0.70 |
12.16 |
121.71 |
18.54 |
140.25 |
1986 |
5.26 |
8.22 |
13.48 |
9.66 |
1.11 |
10.77 |
18.15 |
44.48 |
62.63 |
7.85 |
0.40 |
8.25 |
11.81 |
0.69 |
12.50 |
124.11 |
18.84 |
142.95 |
1987 |
5.57 |
8.48 |
14.05 |
9.42 |
0.91 |
10.33 |
18.62 |
44.10 |
62.72 |
7.89 |
0.40 |
8.29 |
11.85 |
0.58 |
12.43 |
126.90 |
19.17 |
146.07 |
1988 |
5.54 |
8.44 |
13.98 |
9.56 |
0.93 |
10.49 |
18.67 |
43.95 |
62.62 |
8.49 |
0.41 |
8.90 |
12.14 |
0.50 |
12.64 |
128.80 |
19.69 |
148.49 |
1989 |
5.65 |
8.70 |
14.35 |
9.57 |
0.97 |
10.54 |
18.48 |
43.89 |
62.37 |
8.66 |
0.41 |
9.07 |
11.80 |
0.64 |
12.44 |
130.99 |
20.09 |
151.08 |
1990 |
5.55 |
8.68 |
14.23 |
9.56 |
0.96 |
10.52 |
18.63 |
43.83 |
62.46 |
8.69 |
0.39 |
9.08 |
11.46 |
0.69 |
12.15 |
130.58 |
20.00 |
150.58 |
1991 |
5.6 |
8.9 |
14.5 |
10.0 |
1.0 |
11.0 |
18.5 |
44.8 |
63.3 |
9.1 |
0.4 |
9.5 |
11.5 |
0.7 |
12.2 |
136 |
20.9 |
156.9 |
1994 |
5.4 |
8.8 |
14.2 |
10.1 |
1.0 |
11.1 |
17.8 |
46.3 |
64.1 |
9.4 |
0.4 |
9.8 |
11.7 |
0.5 |
12.2 |
140 |
22.3 |
162.3 |
@ Services include (1) trade and commerce, (2)
transport, storage and communications, (3) financing, insurance, real estate,
etc. and (4) public administration. * Data before 1975 are not
comparable with data after 1975 because industrial classification changed
in April 1975. |
Source: Centre for Monitoring Indian Economy. |
Table 7. Sector-wise
number and membership of trade unions submitting returns |
Sector |
The first phase (1950 to mid-1960s) |
The second phase (mid-1960s to 1979) |
The third phase (1980 to 1991) |
The fourth phase (1992 to 2000) |
1958-59 |
1968 |
1986 |
1992 |
|
Number of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions (in '000s) |
Number of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions (in '000s) |
Number of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions (in '000s) |
Number of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions (in '000s) |
|
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Agriculture and allied activities |
121 |
VIII |
447 |
III |
306 |
VI |
487 |
III |
258 |
VI |
288 |
VI |
381 |
VI |
458 |
V |
Mining and quarrying |
123 |
VII |
269 |
IV |
205 |
VIII |
330 |
IV |
142 |
IX |
164 |
VII |
179 |
IX |
154 |
VII |
Manufacturing |
2101 |
I |
1203 |
I |
4222 |
I |
2077 |
I |
3141 |
I |
1707 |
II |
3479 |
I |
2014 |
I |
Construction |
66 |
IX |
50 |
IX |
117 |
IX |
49 |
IX |
158 |
VIII |
314 |
V |
214 |
VIII |
327 |
VI |
Electricity, gas and water |
258 |
VI |
87 |
VIII |
269 |
VII |
161 |
VIII |
195 |
VII |
115 |
IX |
286 |
VII |
76 |
IX |
Commerce |
602 |
II |
141 |
V |
1016 |
III |
277 |
VI |
456 |
V |
121 |
VIII |
451 |
V |
127 |
VIII |
Transport, storage and communication |
454 |
III |
583 |
II |
734 |
IV |
1146 |
II |
833 |
III |
2032 |
I |
1201 |
III |
880 |
III |
Services |
387 |
V |
106 |
VII |
1106 |
II |
279 |
V |
1605 |
II |
918 |
III |
1808 |
II |
745 |
IV |
Activities not adequately described |
442 |
IV |
141 |
V |
434 |
V |
194 |
VII |
763 |
IV |
700 |
IV |
1074 |
IV |
958 |
II |
Source: Indian Labour Yearbook,
Labour Bureau of various years. |
Table 8. Index
numbers of consumer prices (1960-61 to 1993-94) |
Four phases of unionization |
Year |
Index |
Percentage increase over previous year |
|
|
Industrial workers (Base 1982=100) |
Urban non-manual employees (Base 1984-85=100) |
Industrial workers |
Urban non-manual employees |
The first phase (1950
to mid-1960s) |
1960-61 |
20 |
19 |
-- |
-- |
1961-62 |
21 |
20 |
4.0 |
4.0 |
1962-63 |
22 |
20 |
3.8 |
3.8 |
1963-64 |
23 |
21 |
4.6 |
4.6 |
1964-65 |
26 |
23 |
14.2 |
9.7 |
The second phase (mid-1960s to 1979) |
1965-66 |
28 |
25 |
7.8 |
6.5 |
1966-67 |
32 |
27 |
12.9 |
10.6 |
1967-68 |
35 |
30 |
11.5 |
8.9 |
1968-69 |
35 |
30 |
-0.6 |
1.3 |
1969-70 |
36 |
31 |
1.7 |
3.7 |
1970-71 |
38 |
33 |
5.1 |
4.2 |
1971-72 |
39 |
34 |
3.2 |
3.4 |
1972-73 |
42 |
36 |
7.8 |
6.7 |
1973-74 |
51 |
42 |
20.8 |
15.1 |
1974-75 |
64 |
51 |
26.8 |
22.2 |
1975-76 |
63 |
52 |
-1.3 |
2.6 |
1976-77 |
61 |
52 |
-3.8 |
0.0 |
1977-78 |
66 |
56 |
7.6 |
6.9 |
1978-79 |
67 |
58 |
2.2 |
3.4 |
The third phase (1980-1991) |
1979-80 |
73 |
62 |
8.8 |
7.8 |
1980-81 |
81 |
69 |
11.4 |
11.8 |
1981-82 |
91 |
78 |
11.9 |
11.9 |
1982-83 |
99 |
84 |
8.8 |
8.0 |
1983-84 |
111 |
92 |
12.1 |
9.7 |
1984-85 |
118 |
100 |
6.3 |
8.7 |
1985-86 |
126 |
107 |
6.8 |
7.0 |
1986-87 |
137 |
115 |
8.7 |
7.5 |
1987-88 |
149 |
126 |
8.8 |
9.6 |
1988-89 |
166 |
136 |
11.4 |
7.9 |
1989-90 |
173 |
145 |
4.2 |
6.6 |
1990-91 |
193 |
161 |
11.6 |
11.0 |
The fourth phase (1992-2000) |
1991-92 |
219 |
183 |
13.5 |
13.7 |
1992-93 |
240 |
202 |
9.6 |
10.4 |
1993-94 |
258 |
216 |
7.5 |
6.9 |
Source: Basic Statistics: India, August 1994,
Centre for Monitoring Indian Economy. |
Table 9. Index number of wage rates (as in January)
(Base: 1963-65 = 100) |
Four phases of unionization |
Year |
General index for twelve industries |
The second phase (mid-1960s to 1979) |
1969 |
150.3 |
1971 |
174.8 |
1976 |
324.5 |
1978 |
350.6 |
1979 |
376.6 |
The third phase (1980-1991) |
1980 |
421.0 |
1981 |
467.8 |
1982 |
536.2 |
1983 |
588.0 |
1984 |
659.8 |
1985 |
736.3 |
1987 |
887.6 |
1990 |
1159.7 |
1991 |
1304.9 |
The fourth phase (1992-2000) |
1992 |
1480.7 |
1993 |
1626.3 |
Note: Index number of wage rates depict movement of relative
change experienced in the wage rates over a period of time. These indices have
been compiled by the Bureau in selected industries since 1969. Source:
Indian Labour Yearbook, Labour Bureau of various years. |
Table 10. Real wages
in organized manufacturing, 1960/61 - 1983/84 (1960 prices) |
Year |
Real wage (rupees/year) |
Product wage (rupees/year) |
1960/61 |
1197 |
1197 |
1961/62 |
1261 |
1302 |
1962/63 |
1292 |
1317 |
1963/64 |
1363 |
1356 |
1964/65 |
1263 |
1394 |
1965/66 |
1262 |
1450 |
1966/67 |
1264 |
1467 |
1967/68 |
1215 |
1482 |
1968/69 |
1230 |
1557 |
1969/70 |
1345 |
1596 |
1970/71 |
1387 |
1520 |
1971/72 |
1453 |
1501 |
1972/73 |
1436 |
1494 |
1973/74 |
1426 |
1438 |
1974/75 |
1259 |
1351 |
1975/76 |
1426 |
1589 |
1976/77 |
1342 |
1351 |
1977/78 |
1424 |
1519 |
1978/79 |
1627 |
1773 |
1979/80 |
1682 |
1623 |
1980/81 |
1672 |
1447 |
1981/82 |
1632 |
1585 |
1982/83 |
1717 |
1784 |
1983/84 |
1807 |
1938 |
Note: Real wage is nominal wage in manufacturing
deflated by CPI for industrial workers, and product wage is nominal wage deflated
by GDP deflator for manufacturing. Source: Joshi and Little (1994, pp. 92,
120 & 155). |
Table 11. State-wise number and membership of trade
unions submitting returns
State/ union Territory |
The first phase (1950 to mid-1960s) |
The second phase (mid-1960s to 1979) |
The third phase (1980 to 1991) |
The fourth phase (1992 to 2000) |
|
1958-59 |
1968 |
1986 |
1992 |
|
Number of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions (in '000s) |
Number of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions (in '000s) |
Number of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions (in '000s) |
Number of unions submitting returns |
Membership of unions (in '000s) |
|
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Value |
Rank |
Andhra Pradesh |
262 |
VI |
178 |
VIII |
505 |
VI |
277 |
VIII |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Assam |
89 |
IX |
248 |
V |
116 |
XIV |
244 |
IX |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
268 |
VIII |
250 |
VII |
Bihar |
428 |
V |
371 |
III |
525 |
V |
492 |
IV |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Delhi |
233 |
VIII |
216 |
VII |
364 |
VII |
359 |
VI |
294 |
VI |
1009 |
III |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Goa |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
87 |
IX |
37 |
VIII |
89 |
XI |
74 |
XI |
Gujarat |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
273 |
XII |
202 |
X |
744 |
III |
613 |
IV |
1409 |
III |
1329 |
I |
Haryana |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
181 |
XIII |
52 |
XVI |
305 |
V |
260 |
VI |
331 |
VII |
258 |
VI |
Himachal Pradesh |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
53 |
XVI |
11 |
XVII |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Mysore/Karnataka |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
344 |
VIII |
170 |
XI |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
858 |
IV |
393 |
IV |
Kerala |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
809 |
IV |
285 |
VII |
0 |
XIII |
0 |
XIII |
399 |
VI |
202 |
IX |
Madhya Pradesh |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
313 |
X |
127 |
XII |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Bombay/Maharashtra |
1023 |
I |
613 |
II |
1208 |
I |
1034 |
I |
2445 |
II |
2811 |
I |
1668 |
II |
1243 |
III |
Manipur |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
8 |
XX |
2 |
XXI |
56 |
XI |
12 |
X |
111 |
X |
17 |
XII |
Meghalaya |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
0 |
XIII |
0 |
XIII |
31 |
XIII |
12 |
XIII |
Nagaland |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
5 |
XII |
1 |
XII |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Orissa |
60 |
X |
45 |
X |
100 |
XV |
82 |
XV |
105 |
VIII |
112 |
VII |
85 |
XII |
123 |
X |
Punjab |
234 |
VII |
57 |
IX |
329 |
IX |
87 |
XIV |
491 |
IV |
380 |
V |
418 |
V |
335 |
V |
Rajasthan |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
283 |
XI |
108 |
XIII |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
222 |
IX |
207 |
VIII |
Madras/ Tamil Nadu |
746 |
III |
334 |
IV |
1140 |
III |
553 |
II |
2815 |
I |
1102 |
II |
3184 |
I |
1293 |
II |
Tripura |
16 |
XI |
8 |
XI |
22 |
XVIII |
8 |
XVIII |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Uttar Pradesh |
652 |
IV |
242 |
VI |
1208 |
I |
483 |
V |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
West Bengal |
867 |
II |
733 |
I |
1 |
XXI |
511 |
III |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Andaman and Nicobar |
9 |
XII |
3 |
XII |
20 |
XIX |
4 |
XIX |
66 |
X |
12 |
X |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Pondicherry |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
27 |
XVII |
3 |
XX |
145 |
VII |
18 |
IX |
.... |
.... |
.... |
.... |
Source: Indian Labour Yearbook, Labour Bureau, various years. |
Endnote 1:
Both these reports have been reviewed in India in the influential Economic
and Political Weekly. See Breman (1995), Mazumdar (1997) on the World Bank
report, and D'Souza (1998) on the ILO report.
Endnote 2:
There is a substantial literature on the trade union movement in India during
the pre-independence years. Most works on labour history cover trade union
struggles in the Bombay textile industry ( Morris, 1955; 1965) and the Calcutta
jute industry (Chakrabarty, 1989). For an orthodox Marxist approach to the early
working class movement in India see Sen (1977).
Endnote 3:
Statistically, there are three types of trade union in India: those that do not
register and are statistically invisible, those that register but do not submit
returns to the Registrar of Trade Unions on membership size, and those that
register and submit returns on membership figures.
Endnote 4: In the case of the Bombay
Industrial Relations Act of 1946, which imposed an industry-wide bargaining
structure on the textile industry, the INTUC rationalized the check-off system
in the following way: "…the choice of a union must be a well considered
long-term choice, which will be possible only on the basis of an insistence on
continuing paid membership of a union. Temporary excitement and propaganda will
influence the result of an election by secret ballot" (Karnik, 1966, p. 165).
Endnote 5:
V.V. Giri, a veteran trade union leader, served as Labour Minister between 1952-54.
He felt strongly that compulsory adjudication discouraged genuine collective
bargaining, which he tried to make statutory.
Endnote 6:
Internal labour markets are administrative units within which all decisions on
pricing, compensation, promotion, recruitment, and training are determined by
a set of internally-generated rules based on custom, tradition, and past practice.
"Ports of entry" are usually at the lower levels, with workers' careers
rising through predictable paths with assured lifetime employment (see Doeringer
and Piore, 1971 for the original formulation). Wages are attached to jobs rather
than to individual productivity. Internal labour markets seem to thrive during
times of prosperity (when product markets are stable and growing); however with
increased globalization, international competition and computerization, these
markets have become expensive to maintain and reproduce.
Endnote 7:
For a complete list of all statutes governing employment and employment security
see Annex 1 in Mathur (1992).
Endnote 8:
This period is also associated with industrial concentration. An official survey
revealed that in 1964, seventy-five top "business houses" (the
representative unit of Indian capital), controlling less than 6 per cent of all
non-banking firms in the country, owned 47 per cent of total company assets. By
1969, their share had gone up to 54 per cent, with the top twenty houses registering
individual gains of 55 per cent to 196 per cent (Hiro, 1976). Some argued that the
nationalization of major commercial banks in 1970 strengthened the existing monopoly
houses (Bagchi, 1982).
Endnote 9:
This discussion on macroeconomic trends relies heavily on Joshi and Little (1994).
Endnote 10:
According to Joshi and Little (1994: 63): "The above liberalization was not all
that bold looked at from the vantage point of the 1990s, but it was certainly
faster than the funeral pace of 1975/76 to 1984/85. While it can be criticized as
being lopsided in some respects, it was largely pointed in the right direction from
the viewpoint of efficiency and growth".
Endnote 11:
On founding this party, Samant seemed to have voiced a real shopfloor concern of the
times: "We have now realized that workers should have a political party controlled
by them rather than be controlled by the parties". Interview in the Illustrated
Weekly of India, 10-16 February 1985).
Endnote 12:
Trade union membership data in India are notoriously unreliable, as there is a political
economy to its collection and presentation. In addition, the only union membership data
that are available are from those unions that submit returns. Assuming that these are
the large, centralized, politically-affiliated unions, and assuming that the biases do
not change significantly over the years, Bhattacherjee and Datta Chaudhuri
(1994a) estimated trade union growth in India for the period 1962-84 using
a modified Bain and Elsheikh (1976) type equation. Some of their findings
were: increased money wages increased union membership, but not for real
wages (i.e. a strong "credit" effect and a weak "threat"
effect), the unemployment rate negatively affected union membership, and
union density (of unions that submit returns) negatively affected membership
growth. The authors interpret the latter as possibly indicating a saturation
effect of conventional unionism.
Endnote 13:
For an analysis of labour contracts that uses "region" as a proxy for
union and employer preferences for the type of bargaining structure in India,
see Bhattacherjee (1992).
Endnote 14:
Nagaraj (1994) suggests an alternative explanation for the observed wage
increases in the 1980s. Distinguishing sharply between the wage rate and
earnings, and using data from the Occupational Wage Surveys, he suggests
that earnings per worker increased primarily as a result of an increase in
the number of workdays per employee, i.e., an intensification of the labour
process. The latter to him indicates a decline in union power.
Endnote 15:
In an influential academic intervention in Indian labour history, indeed
in labour history in general, Chakrabarty (1989), studying the jute mill
workers in Bengal between 1890 and 1940, heavily criticized the teleological
Marxist narrative of class consciousness and eventual socialist emancipation
(as was dominant in Indian labour history till then). He showed how
"culture" enmeshed the worker's sense of identity, and these
conflicting identities, derived from language, religion and ethnicity, only
further strengthened these divisions. It is this book that has forced the
issues of "working class culture" on to any serious discussion of
labour relations in India today. In the light of what transpires in the fourth
phase, i.e. the growth of ethnic and community-based worker organizations,
the intervention seems to be all the more important.
Endnote 16:
In the orthodox view, structural adjustment is defined as "a process
of market-oriented reforms in policies and institutions, with the goals of
restoring a sustainable balance of payments, reducing inflation, and
creating conditions for sustainable growth in per capita income. Structural
adjustment programmes generally start with a conventional stabilization
programme, intended to restore the viability of the current account and the
budget, but they are distinguished from pure stabilization programmes by
the inclusion of a set of microeconomic-institutional policy reforms"
(Corbo and Fisher, 1995, p. 2847; cited in Nagaraj, 1997). For a completely
different view of what economic liberalization should mean to India's
political economy, one that avoids the extreme positions of both the left
and the right, see Bhaduri and Nayyar (1996).
Endnote 17:
I am grateful to my colleagues, Professors A. Ray and A. Sinha, for permitting
me to use expressions from their unpublished annual economy reports.
Endnote 18:
To get an idea of the magnitude of the problem, consider the following: Steel
Authority of India (SAIL, the public sector giant) has about 170,000 workers
producing 10 million tons of steel, whereas Essar Steel (a private sector firm)
has 1,700 worker producing 2 million tons of steel. In SAIL, several skilled
workers have opted for the voluntary retirement scheme in search of greener
pastures in the private sector (Economic and Political Weekly, 12 June 1999,
p. 1469).
Endnote 19:
The Business Telegraph, (Calcutta), 28 May 1999.
Endnote 20:
In the jute industry for example, (unionized) permanent workers often employ
casual workers (bhagawalas) themselves to meet production targets.
Endnote 21:
The Business Telegraph, (Calcutta), 4 March 1999. This industry-wide
scheme, drawn up by the Indian Banks Association, aims to cover over 10
lakh (1 lakh=100,000) employees in 27 nationalized banks.
Endnote 22:
Five Pay Commissions have been appointed: 1948, 1957, 1970, 1985 and 1995.
Endnote 23:
According to Joseph (1999, p. 1167), "…Indian government employees
enjoy several perks and privileges that are unusual and would be the envy
of their colleagues in other countries. Part of this is a legacy from the
days of British rule in India and part what the employees have been able
to extract from government after independence". Some of these unique
benefits are: commutation of pension, annual accumulation of leave,
reimbursement of petrol and telephone bills.
Endnote 24:
Managers from the coal sector, when questioned about the appalling accident
rates in Indian mines, often state that workers refuse to carry oxygen cylinders
on their backs and demand a wage increase for doing so.
Endnote 25:
ILO, 1997-98, Ch. 5 and 6.
Endnote 26:
According to the state labour department, 17 well known industrial units
have pulled down their shutters during the past year, rendering over 36,000
workers jobless. The McKinsey Report on the state called "Manifesto
for a Business Revolution" has questioned the depth of the state
government's commitment towards industrialization. It has said that though
the new industrial policies framed by the state are commendable, prospective
investors are waiting to see whether pro-investor policies would be followed.
Source: The Sunday Statesman, (Calcutta), 7 February 1999.
Endnote 27:
The Telegraph, (Calcutta), 12 February 1999.
Endnote 28:
The Business Telegraph, (Calcutta), 16 March 1999.
Endnote 29:
The Telegraph, (Calcutta), 25 May 1999.
Endnote 30:
The Telegraph, (Calcutta), 5 June 1999.
Endnote 31:
"The SEWA has been organizing home-based workers in India for
20 years. SEWA members include small artisans like weavers and
carpenters and piece-rate workers like garment and bidi
workers. SEWA is a union of 143,000 members and sponsors cooperatives
to produce alternative employment. So far it has 63 cooperatives
including a cooperative bank and cooperatives providing social
protection like healthcare, childcare and housing to its members"
(Jhabvala, 1995).
Endnote 32:
In 1996, the ILO voted in favour of an international convention on
"homework", defining the latter as "work carried out by
a person in his or her home or in other premises of his or her choice,
other than the workplace of the employer, for remuneration, which
results in a product or service as specified by the employer,
irrespective of who provides the equipment, materials or other inputs
used, unless this person has the degree of autonomy and economic
independence necessary to be considered an independent worker under
laws, regulations or court decisions" (see Mukul,1998).
Updated by RS. Approved by JMS. Last Updated 5 January 2000.
|