Date: Tue, 17 Sep 1996 20:32:28 -0500
From: L-Soft list server at MIZZOU1 (1.8b)
<LISTSERV@MIZZOU1.missouri.edu>
Subject: File: DATABASE OUTPUT
To: Haines Brown <BROWNH@CCSUA.CTSTATEU.EDU>
> S * IN ACTIV-L —> Database ACTIV-L, 9069 hits.
> print 08805
>>> Item number 8805, dated 96/09/09 20:15:33—ALL
Date: Mon, 9 Sep 1996 20:15:33 GMT
Sender: Activists Mailing List <ACTIV-L@MIZZOU1.MISSOURI.EDU>
Subject: U.S. Role In APEC Trade Pact
/** headlines: 138.0 **/
** Topic: U.S. Role In APEC Trade Pact Discussed **
** Written 8:52 PM Sep 4, 1996 by econet in cdp:headlines **
/* Written 9:14 AM Sep 4, 1996 by jagdish in igc:apec.general */
/* ————— APEC's Place in US Trade Policy
— */
From: Jagdish Parikh
<jagdish@igc.apc.org>
———- Forwarded Message Follows ———-
Date: Wed, 4 Sep 1996 14:02:01 +0800 (HKT)
From: daga <daga@HK.Super.NET>
Subject: [asia-apec 90] APEC's Place in US Trade Policy
The US is the powerhouse of APEC, with a $6.7 trillion dollar economy that accounts for close to half of APEC's total GNP.
But perhaps the most telling statistic, the one that is the key to understanding the US's strategy in APEC, is its trade balance with APEC's ten Asian economies. This was a deficit of $120.2 billion in 1995, or over 75 per cent of the total US trade deficit of $159.6 billion. In 1995, the US suffered a trade deficit with all the East Asian economies, with the exception of Korea.
Turning the trade deficit with East Asia into a surplus has been the
driving force of US participation in APEC, where it is leading the
campaign to turn a loose consultative grouping into a free trade area
with fixed rules and schedules for liberalization. While US
negotiators in APEC have offered the vision of a free trade area as a
win-win
situation for everyone, in fact, when they speak
candidly before US institutions like the US Senate, they strike a
different note—one that is distinctly nationalist. For
instance, C. Fred Bergsten, the head of the (now disbanded) Eminent
Persons' Group, told the Senate in November 1994 that the reason
an APEC free trade area is in the US interest is that: Given the
fact that all of the countries in the region, outside North America in
particular, have lots of trade barriers...very little would actually
be required from the United States...So trade liberalization, or
particularly moving to totally free trade in the region, means
enormous competitive gain to the United States.
Washington's drive to institutionalize APEC as a free trade area cannot be understood without placing it in the context of the transformation of US foreign economic policy since the end of the Cold War.
Prior to Ronald Reagan's ascencion to power in 1981, the US's
policy toward Asia consisted of subordinating economic relations with
the region to the overriding priority assigned to the containment of
communism. Thus, Washington, for the most part, tolerated the growing
trade surpluses of its Asian allies, as well as significant deviations
from free market and free trade in their trade, investment, and
domestic economic practices, which could best be characterized as
state-assisted capitalism.
The prosperity of America's
allies was regarded as one of the key weapons in dampening the appeal
of communist revolution in a key battleground of the Cold War.
With the winding down of the Cold War since the mid-eighties, however,
there has occurred a tectonic shift in US foreign economic policy,
with the priority being assigned to opening up
the markets of
US allies to US goods and US investment. Pressures for this shift had
been building for years, and it was based on the growing perception of
both US corporate executives and trade officials that the prosperity
of Japan and the so-called NICs (newly industrializing
countries
) had been purchased at the expense of US economic
interests.
Emblematic of Washington's aggressive new approach were the words
of David Mulford, then undersecretary of the Treasury, at the
Asia-Pacific Capital Markets Conference in San Francisco in 1987:
Although the NICs may be regarded as tigers because they are
strong, ferocious traders, the analogy has a darker side. Tigers live
in the jungle, and by the law of the jungle. They are a shrinking
population.
Washington has employed several weapons in its drive to open up Asian markets and regain a trade and investment presence in a part of the world that has steadily slipped from the US economic orbit. APEC as well as GATT (General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade) must be seen as part of a menu of options, the most prominent of which over the last decade has been unilateral trade pressure. With the US market continuing to account for 20 to 25 per cent of the exports of many Asian economies, unilateralism, or a strategy based on the threat and use of trade retaliation, has been an attractive option.
A wide range of unilateralist weapons has been deployed against Asian economies over the last decade.
unfair tradersor
abettorsof the intellectual property rights (IPRs) of US corporations. This year, for instance, most of the US's APEC trade partners made what is now known as the US Trade Representative's Office
hit listof IPR violators: China was on top of the list as a
priority foreign country;Japan, Indonesia, and Korea achieved the distinction of being on the
priority watch list;and the Philippines and Thailand were placed on the
watch list.
Unilateralist trade diplomacy (an oxymoron this!) has been regarded as
highly successful by Washington officials. Commerce Secretary Mickey
Kantor has boasted that under President Clinton's leadership,
the Administration has negotiated nearly 200 agreements to open
foreign markets, which has helped fuel record growth and the creation
of one million jobs.
Other officials promised the continuation of
the same policy of achieving practical, market-based,
results-oriented agreements
carried out with the stated or
unstated threat of invoking Super 301.
As prima facie evidence of the virtues of unilateralism, US trade officials refer to the case of South Korea. When Korea developed a $9.7 billion surplus with the US in 1987, US trade officials saw the emergence of another Japan, and they moved decisively to head it off at the pass. A whole panoply of weapons—anti-dumping suits, import restrictions, Super 301, Special 301, currency appreciation, etc.—was employed on the most successful Asian tiger in an all-encompassing assault that targetted, among other sectors, agriculture, telecommunications, maritime services, financial services, the foreign investment regime, the fishing industry, cosmetics, and government procurement practices. By 1991, the US deficit with Korea had turned into a surplus, and in 1995, Korea was the only East Asian economy with which the United States enjoyed a surplus in its trade account.
Unilateralism is, however, merely one prong of US policy towards its
trading partners. The unilateralist approach is complemented by a
multilateralist
game plan and a regional
strategy. The
multilateralist prong has been an effort to make the General Agreement
on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) a medium for the reduction of trade
barriers globally as well as an iron framework of global rules
governing trade and trade-related acitivties. The regional thrust has
led to the creation of free trade areas like the North American Free
Trade Area (NAFTA) and APEC, where greater concessions on trade than
were obtainable under GATT can be negotiated with selected trade
partners.
While in the view of its trading partners, unilateralism contradicts multilateralism as a way of resolving trade disputes, in the US view, these are complementary approaches that are tied together by the goal of achieving freer trade. But Washington's commitment to free trade is hardly doctrinal. It is a pragmatic position based on the assessment that free trade at this point translates into US competitive advantage. Again, this is evident in the case of GATT. If the US was committed to the passage of the Uruguay Round of GATT, this was based not on a benign vision of everyone gaining from free trade in an equitable fashion, but of the US gaining disproportionately from it. As EPG chief Bergsten told the US Congress, under GATT, the US would derive greater benefits from GATT than others because while foreign tariffs on US exports would come down by 40 per cent on the average, US tariff cuts would amount to only 32-33 per cent on the average.
More broadly, Washington believes that the so-called level playing
field
introduced by freer trade under GATT will translate into a
tremendous advantage for US corporations, whose size, resources, and
technological edge, would allow them to beat a competition shorn of
the artificial advantage conferred by protectionist laws, subsidies,
cheap credit, state-supported research and development, and other
mechanisms of the state assisted capitalism
that is the
hallmark of East Asian economies.
But GATT also illustrates that the US commitment to free trade is
conditional, not doctrinal. For when the freer flow of resources
contradicts powerful US interests, Washington supports a position
under GATT that reinforces monopoly or oligopoly instead of promoting
free trade. This is the case with the GATT Agricultural Accord, which
is basically an entente cordiale between the US and the European Union
on the question of dumping their highly subsidized agricultural
surpluses on third-country markets. While the Accord commits all
signatories, including Third World countries, to reduce export
subsidies, it institutionalizes the direct income subsidies provided
by the US government and the European Union for their farmers. As
economist Brian Gardner notes, the agreement merely swaps one form of
subsidization for another, taking away direct support of markets
and replacing it with direct subsidization of [northern] farmers.
It is estimated that in 1995, the first year of the implementation of
the GATT Uruguay Round, 20 per cent of the cost of US farm production
was financed by state subsidies totalling $25 billion.
This, of course, has massive implications for the Asia-Pacific countries, whose agricultural markets have been targetted by the United States Department of Agriculture to absorb 60 per cent of US agricultural exports by the year 2000, up from the figure of 40 per cent at present.
Another GATT agreement that reinforces monopoly instead of the free
flow of resources is the accord on trade-related intellectual
property rights
(TRIPs). This accord was pushed by Washington with
the full support of Bill Gates and the US high tech lobby that wanted
to tighten up what it considered a loose framework of global rules
that was facilitating too free and too fast a flow of technological
innovation from the North to the South. By institutionalizing such
draconian measures as a generalized minimum patent protection of 20
years and placing the burden of proof on those accused of patent
infringement, the accord represents what UNCTAD describes as a
premature strengthening of the international intellectual proerty
system...that favors monopolistically contolled innnovation over
broad-based diffusion.
As many observers have noted, the main targets of the TRIPs accord
have been Japan, Korea, and the East Asian NICs that have successfully
mounted industrialization-by- imitation,
particularly in
knowledge-intensive industries.
Like GATT, APEC is a key element of US trade strategy. However, APEC offers US trade officials advantages that GATT lacks.
GATT-plus arrangementwhere the US can extract more trade and trade-related concessions from its partners than they were willing to grant under the GATT Uruguay Round Agreement. An example of this was the 1995 proposal of Bergsten's Eminent Persons' Group that APEC members should reduce by half the transition period for implementing trade liberalization and full adoption of other trade-related reforms that they had already committed themselves to under GATT. For instance, in this proposal, APEC's developing economies would make their legislation governing intellectual property rights GATT-consistent by 1998 instead of the Uruguay Round deadline of 2000.
marginalizethe US from the Asia-Pacific, such as the fact that intra-Asian trade as a proportion of total Asian trade has risen from an already high 47 per cent in 1990 to 53 per cent in 1995. What worries people such as Clinton adviser Paula Stern is that Asia might be moving toward becoming an integrated market and production base, whose trade dependence on the US will increasingly decrease. A trans-Pacific APEC free trade area is, in this sense, a preemptive move against proposals such as Malaysian Prime Minister Mohamad Mahathir's
East Asia Economic Caucus,a formation that would include only the Asian economies with the intention of forging even closer trading and investment ties among them. In Washington's view, the institutionalization of APEC would eliminate such efforts to
place an artificial dividing line down the center of the Pacific,as Assistant Secretary of State Winston Lord puts it.
reformingtheir economies. Via APEC mechanisms, the US can build pressure for the dismantling of the heavy state presence in the economies of its Asian trading partners—an
interventionistpresence that US officials consider the
motherof all trade and investment barriers to the US private sector. As Undersecretary of State Joan Spero put it before a US congressional committee:
APEC has a customer. APEC is not for governments; it is for business. Through APEC, we aim to get government out of the way, opening the way for business to do business.
In sum, an APEC free trade area must be seen as an integral part of a broader foreign economic policy that employs the rhetoric of free trade but is driven by economic realpolitik, by a determined drive to regain global economic primacy for the US.
Mickey Kantor is the personification of this approach. Proudly
admitting that he is a non-economist, the US Secretary of Commerce
candidly declares to one and all that his mission consists of one
thing, and one thing only: to pry markets wide open in order to drive
down the US trade deficit. Kantor is not a doctrinal free trader but
one who can just as readily appeal to nationalist sentiment as to free
trade in pursuit of his perception of US economic interest. Washington
insiders contend that Kantor told Clinton in depending on
Clinton's political needs of the moment. Perhaps, the spirit of
economic realpolitik that pervades the Clinton administration's
foreign economic policy is best captured by Kantor's celebrated
assertion before the US Senate in April 1994: We will continue to
use every tool at our disposal—301 Super 301, Special 301, Title
VII, GSP, the Telecommunications Trade Act, or WTO accessi! onto open
markets around the globe.